Skip to main content

The Official Journal of the Pan-Pacific Association of Input-Output Studies (PAPAIOS)

Eliminating Indirect Energy Subsidies in Ukraine: Estimation of Environmental and Socioeconomic Effects Using Input–Output Modeling

Abstract

Energy subsidies are causing adverse effects on the economy and environment stimulating inefficient resource allocation and excessive energy consumption. Therefore, multiple positive effects are likely to be obtained if subsidies are reduced or removed completely. This study estimates indirect end-user energy subsidies in gas and electricity sectors of Ukraine and assesses short-term environmental and socioeconomic effects of a hypothetical elimination of these subsidies. Consumer subsidies are quantified utilizing the price-gap approach that compares end-user prices and reference prices that would predominate in competitive markets where no subsidies are provided. Input–output analysis is undertaken to investigate impacts in the short-term. First, a price model is utilized to estimate price changes resulting from subsidy elimination and then a demand-driven IO model is adopted for estimation of associated changes of environmental and social variables. As a result of elimination of energy subsidies, total energy consumption and GHG emissions would decline by about 2.5 % and 3.6 %, respectively. In addition, distributional effects of a subsidy reform are analyzed utilizing data on consumption patterns of different income groups.

JEL Classification: D57, P22, P28, Q41.

1 Introduction

In order to mitigate climate change and accelerate transition toward a more sustainable development path, massive investments are required for energy efficient and renewable energy technologies. Instead, large amounts of money are spent annually to stimulate production and consumption of conventional energy. Governments provide support either explicitly through subsidies or implicitly through interventions in energy prices and fuel allocation. Theoretically, subsidies could be justified if they increase overall social welfare. However, fossil-fuel subsidies are seen as having a net negative effect since they distort the economy and stimulate environmental deterioration (Ellis [2010]). Although in OECD countries energy subsidies have decreased considerably over the past two decades, subsidies are still pervasive in developing countries and transition economies (UNEP [2004]).

Direct state support for energy sectors is not large in Ukraine compared to very high implicit subsidies due to under-pricing of energy products. Gas, electricity, and district heating tariffs for households are set by the state at very low rates, which do not reflect full costs for maintenance and capital investments (IEA [2006b]). Underpricing of energy distorts the economy of Ukraine and is one of the most important factors of its persistently high energy-intensity. As of 2009, it was at the level of 0.40 Total Primary Energy Supply (TPES)/GDP (ppp) (toe per 1000 USD at 2000 prices) compared to 0.37 for non-OECD Europe and Eurasia and a world average of 0.19TPES/GDP (ppp) (IEA [2011a]). Energy consumption is also responsible for a large share of GHG emissions of the country. In particular, GHG emissions from fuel combustion amounted to 240.6 million tons CO2-eq., i.e., 57 % of the total country emissions in 2008 (MENR [2010]).

In the early 1990s, GHG emissions of the country had fallen drastically as a result of the collapse of the Soviet Union and resultant crash of the national economy with a GDP drop of about 50 % (SSCU [2009a]) in 1995 compared to 1990 levels. Nevertheless, Ukraine is among the top 20 largest CO2 emitters in the world (United Nations Statistics Division [2010]), with one of the highest carbon intensities of 0.89 kg CO2-eq/GDP (PPP), which is slightly higher than for non-OECD Europe and Eurasia, but almost twice as large as the world average (IEA [2011a]).

Since the mid-1990s, the economy has gradually recovered and GHG emissions have started to rise. However, in situations of frequent political instability and heavy economic and social problems, environmental issues and climate change in particular are far from being a priority on the political agenda.

A number of modeling studies show evidence that reduction or elimination of energy subsidies could bring environmental and economic gains (for a good review, see Ellis [2010]). Similarly, the IEA ([1999]) suggests that elimination of energy subsidies is likely to address all three dimensions of sustainable development. Environmental benefits would be obtained through efficient pricing leading to reductions of environmental pollution. Social welfare could be improved by redirecting public funds spent on subsidies toward social needs. Economic advantages could be derived from increased efficiency of resource allocation and reduced public expenditures.

A number of studies have been undertaken to estimate environmental and economic impacts of phasing out energy subsidies in developing and transition economies (e.g., Saboochi [2001]; Saunders and Schneider [2000]; Lin and Jiang [2011]). However, according to our knowledge, no papers have previously analyzed the likely effects of the removal of end-user energy subsidies (i.e., energy price distortions) for the Ukrainian context. In addition, conclusions derived for Ukraine could also be relevant for other transition economies since the majority of post-Soviet countries inherited highly energy-intensive economies due to relative abundance of energy resources in the Soviet Union and state control of energy prices. Therefore, the objective of this study is to estimate end-user energy subsidies in gas and electricity sectors of Ukraine and assess environmental and socioeconomic effects of a hypothetical elimination of energy subsidies.

The paper does not consider direct subsidies (i.e., direct payments made by the government) either to consumers or producers but focuses on implicit consumer subsidies following the definition and approach of the International Energy Agency ([1999]). We adopted a broad definition of energy subsidies as any government policies or measures could directly or indirectly influence prices or costs. These subsidies are estimated as a price-gap between actual prices and market prices, which would prevail in the absence of subsidies. In this paper, we focus only on consumer subsidies in electricity and gas sectors. Indirect consumer subsidies for the oil and coal sector are not considered since previous studies have shown that prices of oil products are close to market levels and consumer subsidies for coal did not take place in Ukraine (e.g., IEA [2006a, 2008, 2011b]).

Section 2 provides an overview of the previous estimates of energy subsidies in Ukraine and reviews the literature for environmental and socioeconomic effects of a hypothetical subsidy reform. Section 3 elucidates theoretical underpinnings of the price-gap approach and input–output analysis, describes the data utilized in the analysis, and points out limitations of this paper. Section 4 presents the main findings of the study. Finally, conclusions and policy implications of the hypothetical energy subsidy reform are summarized in Sect. 5.

2 An Overview of Previous Estimates of Energy Subsidies in Ukraine and Impact Assessments of Removal of Subsidies

First estimations of energy subsidies for developing countries and economies in transition are dating back to the 1990s. For example, the pioneering study by Larsen and Shah ([1992]) estimated energy subsidies in the countries of the former Soviet Union amounting to 172 billion USD. However, only few estimates have been carried specifically for Ukraine. Perhaps, the first one and the most detailed to date is the case study prepared by Petri et al. ([2002]) that computed quasi-fiscal activities in gas and electricity sectors being equal to 6.5 % of GDP in 2000. Saavalainen and Berge ([2006]) calculated the quasi-fiscal deficit for the same sectors as being 5.3 % and 3.1 % of GDP, respectively. Legeida ([2001]) analyzed both explicit and implicit subsidies in Ukraine’s economy in 2000. IEA ([2006a, 2008]) calculated consumer energy subsidies from under-pricing for the 20 largest non-OECD countries. According to IEA’s estimates, in Ukraine subsidies for gas consumption reached about 12 billion USD in 2005 and 10 billion USD in 2007. Subsidies for electricity were significantly lower, 2.5 billion USD in 2005 and around 4 billion USD in 2007.

Estimation of macroeconomic effects of energy price shocks is an important and a well-established field of research; numerous studies have been carried out to investigate effects of steep increases of energy prices at the international and regional level as well as for individual countries (e.g., Bohi [1991]; IEA [2004]; Lardic and Mingnon [2006]; Nasseh and Elyasiani [1984]; World Bank [2005]). The gas conflict between Russia and Ukraine in 2006 and resultant abrupt price increase of imported gas stimulated research on the effects of energy price shocks on Ukraine’s economy. For example, the Institute for Economic Research and Policy Consulting (IER) in Ukraine ([2006]) estimated, using a Computable General Equilibrium (CGE) model, that an increase of the gas price by 60 % triggered by a sharp price increase of imported gas could result in an annual 5.5 % decline of real GDP and about a 20 % decrease of total welfare in the medium-term (about 7–10 years) after the economy has fully adjusted to the external price shock. Chemical industry and metallurgy are expected to be the most vulnerable with about 80 % decline of aggregate output. It has been estimated that in order to mitigate the effect of a large price increase, i.e., prevent the drop of real GDP, domestic gas consumption should be reduced by 36 %, which equals a 12 % decline of the energy-intensity of the economy. Another study by IER ([2007]) has shown that energy market reforms coupled with investment in energy efficiency and expansion of domestic gas production could counteract negative effects of energy price shocks. In particular, an approximate three times increase of the domestic price of gas and about 2 times for electricity and heat could reduce total primary energy supply (TPES) by about 50 % over a 10-year time horizon.

A World Bank ([2005]) study utilized a simple Net Import Model to quantify short-term effects of oil and gas price shocks on Ukraine’s economy. Depending on the scenarios employed, GDP would decline within the range of 0.4–8.6 % for the first year of the price shock and 0.2–6 % of GDP during the second year. Flanagan et al. ([2007]) used statistical modeling to quantify effects of a 10 % increase in the import price of gas over the short and medium-term period. In the near term (1 year), output could decline from 0.09 % to 0.43 % (depending on the method) and inflation could increase by up to 1.17 %. Mid-term effects on output would be higher (from 0.47 % to 0.50 %) while inflation rate could decrease to 1.06 %.

In spite of all modeling estimates, Ukraine’s economy has proven to be more resilient to external price shocks than expected. GDP growth remained positive in 2006 and even counteracted declining tendencies recorded in 2005 (Pirani [2007]). The author notes that the main reasons for this are high prices of exporting products, particularly metals, energy efficiency improvements, and consumption-induced growth of the economy.

Historically, energy subsidies have been introduced to ameliorate important social issues; however, it might not have been the most efficient method to address them. The only case when energy subsidies could be justified is when increasing energy production and consumption beyond economically efficient levels is the only possible way to achieve important policy targets, which is very difficult to prove in reality. In fact, direct transfer of funds could be a more efficient approach to deal with social problems than subsidizing energy consumption (IEA [1999]). For example, Kebede ([2006]) examined the effectiveness of energy subsidies for kerosene and electricity in Ethiopia and came to the conclusion that subsidies benefit more nonpoor households than low income groups.

Similar to carbon pricing policies, removal of subsidies is likely to have negative distribution effects (Feng et al. [2010]; Kerkhof et al. [2008]) since low income groups are usually spending a larger share of their income on utilities, which would increase prices considerably if gas and electricity subsidies are abolished. A number of studies were carried out previously to examine distributional effects of energy subsidy reform in developing countries (Gangopadhyay et al. [2005]; Kebede [2006]; Parvin and Banouei [2009]; Soheir et al. [2009]). For example, Saboohi ([2001]) found evidence that negative effects could be minimized and net income of the poor in Iran could even increase if the energy subsidy reform is accompanied by a mechanism of recycling back of some revenues to lower income households.

A limited amount of literature is available on the affordability of basic utility services and susceptibility of price increases for low-income households in transition countries (e.g., Fankhauser and Tepic [2007]; Fankhauser et al. [2008]; Lampietti et al. [2001]; Lampietti and Meyer [2002]; Lovei et al. [2000]). Dodonov et al. ([2004]) examined vulnerability of poor households in Ukraine to increases of electricity tariffs and came to conclusion that adjusting electricity prices up to cost-covering levels estimated by the National Electricity Regulation Commission (NERC) would not cause considerable welfare losses for households. However, the authors claim that further increases up to the average OECD levels, to reflect long-run marginal production costs, could have adverse social consequences and should be implemented in a stepwise fashion.

Elimination of subsidies is the initial step for establishing the level of emissions at the “socially optimal level” with the subsequent implementation of carbon pricing policies aiming to internalize externalities (World Bank [1997]). However, in situations when energy prices simply do not reflect opportunity costs or long-run marginal production costs in developing countries and economies in transition, phasing out energy subsidies alone could be perceived as effective climate mitigation policy. Since energy consumption and GHG emissions are intrinsically coupled, a price-induced decrease of energy use would eventually result in reduction of GHG emissions. For example, Burniaux et al. ([2009]) estimated using the OECD ENV-Linkages model that gradual elimination of subsidies over the period from 2013 to 2020 (assuming no other mitigation policies are taken) would result in a 20 % reduction in CO2 emissions in Russia and other non-EU Eastern European countries.

3 Methodology

3.1 Price-Gap Approach

The underlying presumption of the price-gap approach is that energy subsidies decrease prices of energy goods and services, thereby, leading to increase in consumption. The “price gap” is the difference between final consumer prices and reference prices that would dominate in competitive markets where no subsidies are provided to either consumers or producers (IEA [1999]). Theoretical underpinnings of the methodology were developed by Corden ([1957]). Larsen and Shah ([1992]) applied the price-gap approach for quantification of global fossil-fuel consumption subsidies. Later, the method was used by the IEA ([1999, 2006a, 2006b, 2008]) for estimation of energy subsidies in the largest non-OECD countries.

The price-gap approach is described in detail by IEA ([1999]). The basic idea to compare end-user energy prices with reference prices is very simple; however, practical application of the method is less straightforward since some assumptions need to be made for calculation of reference prices. End-user prices correspond to actual energy prices paid by final consumers. These prices reflect current energy pricing policy of a country and incorporate all taxes and fees as well as reductions and rebates imposed on energy products and services. Reference prices indicate the prices at undistorted market and reflect full opportunity cost of energy consumption. Either international market prices or long-run marginal cost of production could be used as a benchmark for reference prices of energy products. For traded goods, the reference price is calculated based on the export or import border price, for nontraded products, production cost forms the basis. Importantly, border price and domestic production cost should be equal to an ‘ideal’ competitive market. Domestic production cost should be estimated based at the international price even if the product could be produced domestically at the lower cost (OECD [2010]). Internal transportation and distribution costs are also incorporated in the reference price. In addition, Value Added Tax (VAT) and other country-specific general transaction taxes should be included. These taxes “are part of the cost of doing business” and do not influence comparative prices between energy products and other goods, and hence, economic efficiency of resource allocation (p. 76 in IEA [1999]). However, energy taxes should not be used for calculation of reference prices since they partly offset subsidy-induced effects on final prices and consumption. Therefore, subsidies for final energy and gas consumers in Ukraine are calculated utilizing the following equation:

S c =Q( P r P)
(1)

where S c is defined as consumer subsidies for gas or electricity, P—end-user price including subsidies, P r —estimated reference price excluding subsidies and Q—total consumption of gas or electricity. Final prices are differentiated depending on the consumer group, quantity of energy consumed (the price increases with higher energy consumption), and availability of meters. Since energy consumption data for each group of consumers (with different energy consumption and with or without meters) is not available at a very detailed (price differentiation) level, it was decided to compare actual cost, reported by the Ministry of Fuel and Energy (MFE [2009]) and estimated reference cost for a given quantity of energy consumed. Thus, Eq. (1) could be presented in the following way:

S c = C r C a
(2)

where C a =PQ is defined as actual cost of gas or electricity consumed at the current end-user prices reported by the Ministry of Fuel and Energy of Ukraine (MFE [2009]) and C r = P r Q is defined as cost in an undistorted market. Reference price and cost for gas is estimated based on the price of imported gas and adjusted for transportation and distribution costs and 20 % value added tax (VAT). A special surcharge coefficient on the gas price is also included since it works not as classical energy tax levied on energy to reduce energy consumption or emissions. On the contrary, the revenues generated by the surcharge are used for gasification of new territories and compensation of the losses of Naftogaz (holding the largest share of the oil and gas market in Ukraine) from selling gas to district heating companies. Therefore, the surcharge contributes to full costs of the product and investment needs, which should be included in prices of all goods and services. Hence, the surcharge does not distort relative prices between energy products and other goods. A special surcharge coefficientFootnote 1 is used as a coefficient on cost of gas excluding transportation and distribution tariffs and VAT. The duty aiming to compensate expenditures of Naftogaz on selling gas to households has also been included for the same reasons. Therefore, reference cost of gas, C rg (in Ukrainian Hryvnia, UAH) is expressed as

C rg = Q g ( P im + C s + T tg + T dg )(1+VAT)+ S s Q g ( P im + C s )
(3)

where Q g is total consumption of gas (in 1000 m3), P im (in UAH per 1000 m3) is the price of gas at the border, C s (in UAH per 1000 m3)—cost of selling gas incurred by Naftogaz, S s —special surcharge coefficient; T tg and T dg transportation and distribution tariffs (in UAH per 1000 m3), respectively. In 2008, the price of imported gas was at 945.5 UAH per 1000 m3 which approximately equals 179.5 USD.Footnote 2 Average 2008 values of other price components provided by the National Electricity Regulation Commission (NERC [2009]) and Ministry of Fuel and Energy ([2009]) are used in estimates. Since Ukraine less actively participates in electricity trade (about 4 % is exported according to NERC [2009]) with other countries compared to other types of energy, long-term production cost is a more appropriate benchmark for estimation of subsidies than the export border price. According to NERC ([2009]), the wholesale market price (for suppliers) reflects all operational costs and incorporates surcharge for some investments. However, current tariffs are not high enough to compensate for depreciation and investment needs in nuclear, hydro, and most thermal power plants (IEA [2006b]). According to the Energy Strategy of Ukraine (MFE [2006]), the electricity sector requires around 196 billion UAH (37 billion USD) of investment during the period from 2006 to 2010, which means approximately 39 billion UAH (7 billion USD) annually. MFE ([2009]) reports that about 5 billion UAH (0.95 billion USD) of capital investment have been utilized by the energy sector from all sources (including surcharge) in 2008. Hence, investment deficit amounted to around 34 billion UAH (6.5 billion USD) or 0.27 UAH/kWh (0.05 USD/kWh) for approximately 125 billion kWh of electricity consumed in 2008 (MFE [2009]). Therefore, prices should be increased by about 0.27 UAH/kWh in order to reflect long-run production costs. This approach is especially relevant because the government perceives optimization of the price and tariff policy as one of the most important mechanisms of investment in the energy sector (MFE [2006]). In addition, the wholesale price should be first adjusted to eliminate cross-subsidization of households by industrial consumers. The price used in calculations is reduced by 23.7 % (proportion of cross-subsidization) (NERC [2009]). Therefore, reference cost of electricity C re (in UAH) is calculated as follows:

C re = Q e ( P w + I d + T te + T se )(1+VAT)
(4)

where Q e —total electricity consumed (in kWh), P w —wholesale price for suppliers (in UAH/kWh), I d —investment deficit (in UAH/kWh), T te and T se —transmission and supply tariffs for electricity (in UAH/kWh). Average 2008 prices and tariffs in the electricity sector published by National Electricity Regulation Commission (NERC [2009]) are used in the estimates.

Despite the fact that price-gap metric is widely applied for cross-country studies (e.g., Burniaux et al. [1992]; IEA [1999]; Larsen and Shah [1992]), due to its relative simplicity and low level of data requirements, it has a number of important limitations described by Koplow ([2009]) and IEA ([1999]).

3.2 Estimating Price Effects on Environmental and Socioeconomic Factors

3.2.1 Input–Output (IO) Price Model

Input–output analysis is carried out for estimation of environmental and socioeconomic effects from phasing-out energy subsidies in the gas and electricity sectors of Ukraine. We have chosen IO approach because it is a well established and the most transparent methodology appropriate for addressing research questions set in this paper. As demonstrated in Ginsburgh and Keyzer ([1997]), input–output models can be regarded as simplified general equilibrium models or satisfactory approximation to general equilibrium models when the modeling focus is on short-term analyses of one-shot policy shocks like the price-gap elimination specified in this paper. In addition, this study utilizes both the demand-driven and price IO model to establish the link between changes of relative prices and quantities of goods demanded, thus incorporating the essence of a CGE model without burdening itself with the complex and data-demanding work of constructing a fully fledged CGE model. While a CGE model is capable of assessing structural and technological change effects of policy shocks, this study argues that it is important to study short-run consequences for the purpose of developing mitigation strategies as unwillingness to encounter additional costs usually impedes necessary policy reforms. Another advantage of the IO methodology is that it allows explicitly examining industry interdependency, in the case of this research, how elimination of subsidies in gas and electricity sectors triggers changes in other sectors.

The study builds on the dual nature of the input–output system and utilizes both the demand-driven and price IO model. In addition, partial equilibrium analysis is incorporated within an IO framework to establish the link between changes of relative prices and quantities of goods demanded.

The Leontief price model is the starting point of the analysis. The model reflects that the total price of one unit of output is equal to total costs of its production including intermediate purchases and primary inputs. Thus, the basic equation of the Leontief price model is usually expressed as follows:

p = v ( I A ) 1 = v L
(5)

where p is a row vector of prices of produced commodities by each sector and v denotes a row vector of primary inputs per one monetary unit of price; I is the identity matrix; ( I A ) 1 is the Leontief inverse L or total requirements matrix.

This study adopts the IO price model for estimation of changes in relative prices as a result of elimination of implicit subsidies in electricity and gas sectors. This will lead to price increases of commodities of other sectors, which require gas and electricity for production and resources from other sectors which, in turn, purchase energy as intermediate inputs. Thus, the final change of relative prices is caused by direct and indirect effects of price increases for energy. A price shock caused by phasing out subsidies in gas and electricity sectors could be recorded as a change of value-added of these sectors. Therefore, relative changes of prices for a change in primary inputs could be estimated as follows:

Δ p =Δ v L
(6)

where Δ v is a row vector of changes in the primary inputs and Δ p is a vector of price changes. In other words, similar to an imposition of a tax, elimination of consumer subsidies for gas and electricity is recorded as a change of value added, Δ v , for sectors in oil and gas extraction and electricity production, respectively, to estimate resultant price changes, Δ p , and distributional effects (see Eq. (7)).

3.2.2 Estimating CPI Changes for Different Income Groups

The input–output price model is also used to quantify welfare impacts of energy subsidies reform utilizing data on consumption patterns of households classified per income level (from the lowest income, 1st group, to the highest, 11th group) and by area of residence, in particular, households living in rural areas and in urban areas (SSCU [2009b]).

We adopt a fairly standard Laspeyres price index (see, e.g., ILO [2004]), which assumes a fixed structure of goods and services, to estimate a change of the Consumer Price Index (CPI) or additional income required for purchasing the same basket of goods and services as follows:

Δ CPI h = j β h j Δ p j
(7)

where Δ CPI h refers to the change in consumer price index (in %), h indexes households with different income levels and areas of residence, and β h j is the budget share of commodity j for each group of households—h, reported by State Statistics Committee of Ukraine (SSCU [2009b]), and Δ p j is a relative price change (in %) of each sector’s commodity j estimated with Eq. (6). Subscript j denotes the element in column of the matrix.

A time horizon is not explicitly defined in this paper. Since technological change is not foreseen in the methodology adopted and direct input coefficients remain constant, only short-term effects are studied assuming that the economy does not have time for structural adjustment and substitution between energy and nonenergy factors of production.

3.2.3 Partial Equilibrium Approach

The underlying assumption of the price model is that changes in value added lead to changes in relative prices of goods and services but the quantities of goods demanded remain constant. However, economic theory suggests that in response to higher prices on normal goods, i.e., decrease in real income, rational consumers would either reduce purchases of given commodities, substitute for the cheaper ones or maintain the same level of consumption at the expense of other products. Therefore, we aim to estimate the response of final consumers to increased prices of goods and services. At the same time, industries are unable to adjust their input structure as technical coefficients are fixed in the input–output model. This is one of the most important limitations of the IO methodology, but still consistent in the short run since industries are unable to change technological processes immediately and would need more time and additional investments. Thus, we assume that all costs will be passed on to final consumers, which are more capable of responding to price shocks in the short run. Households have a number of measures available which could be relatively easily implemented to mitigate rapid increase of utilities tariffs. At the moment, residential energy consumption in Ukraine is about 250–275 kWh/m2 compared to 120 kWh/m2 in Western Europe (World Bank [2012]). Moreover, 80 % of buildings do not even have heat meters installed (IEA [2012]). It is estimated that heat meters installation could reduce heat consumption by 15–25 % decreasing heating costs by about 10–15 % (World Bank [2012]). Water consumption by households is also very high in Ukraine compared to the EU countries. The main reason for this is that water supply tariffs are very low and do not even cover operational costs in the majority of the regions. In addition, tariffs are based on weighted average rather than actual consumption and most of households do not have water meters installed (see, e.g., EBRD [2011]; OECD [2007]).

A partial equilibrium approach is used to establish the link between price changes estimated by price model with changes in final demand derived from the classical demand driven model. The basic relationship between changes of prices and quantities of final demand could be expressed as follows:

ε= Δ Q P Q Δ P
(8)

where ε is the price elasticity of final demand for output, P and Q initial price and quantity and ΔP and ΔQ are changes of prices and quantity. A change of quantity demanded, ΔQ, as a result of price changes could be estimated as follows:

ΔQ= ε Q Δ P P
(9)

notation (9) in matrix algebra is expressed as

Δy=Δ p ˆ ε ˆ y 0
(10)

where y 0 is the initial vector of final demand, Δy, column vector of change in final demand, Δ p ˆ diagonal matrix (a matrix with the elements of the vector in the main diagonal and zeros in outside the main diagonal) of price changes (in % or share of unity) and ε ˆ diagonal matrix of elasticities. In other words, we diagonalize the vector of price changes Δ p (obtained with Eq. (6)) to receive a diagonal matrix Δ p ˆ and use y 0 , initial vector of final demand recorded in the IO table, and ε ˆ diagonal matrix of elasticities (see Table 1) to estimate a change in final demand, Δy, which is then used in subsequent steps of the analysis.

Table 1 Price elasticities of demand for output

Unfortunately, consistent estimates of price elasticities for most commodities are often not available. There are numerous studies on price sensitivity of energy consumption showing energy consumption likely to be relatively inelastic in the short-run since few substitution options are available for households (e.g., Cohn [1980]; Prosser [1985]; Bentzen and Engsted [1993]; Bernstein and Griffin [2006]). Atakhanova and Howie ([2007]) estimated short and long-run price-elasticity of residential electricity consumption as of −0.22 and −1.10. Nahata et al. ([2007]) obtained comparable results for urban and rural households in Russia. Some research has been carried out on demand sensitivity of agricultural commodities and food products to price changes, which are also likely to be inelastic in the short-term (e.g., Andrikopoulos et al. [1987]; Russo et al. [2008]) and transportation services (Wohlgemuth [1997]). However, it is especially difficult to find elasticities for certain industries, especially, for effects in the short-run. Considering limited availability of real estimates of price sensitivity for all economic sectors, Ho et al. ([2008]) derived elasticities from a macroeconomic model for the US under constrained conditions; Choi et al. ([2010]) adopted assumptions on several scenarios for price elasticities. This study assumes that similar sectors would have similar price elasticities (see Table 1). This assumption was made due to limited evidence from the literature (e.g., Atakhanova and Howie [2007]; Ho et al. [2008]; Nahata [2007]; Russo [2008]; Wohlgemuth [1997]).

3.2.4 Input–Output Demand-Driven Model

At the next stage of analysis, the classical Leontief (see, e.g., Miller and Blair [2009]) IO model is utilized to estimate demand-induced changes of the total output and associated changes of employment, total energy, and gas consumption and GHG emissions.

A change of total output Δx as a result of change in final demand Δy (calculated with Eq. (10)) is estimated as

Δx= ( I A ) 1 Δy=LΔy
(11)

A decrease in gross outputs would result in decline in resource consumption, emissions or other factors. The IO model is extended to examine these effects as well. Similar to the coefficients in the A matrix, physical coefficients b i are calculated by dividing emissions e i of each sector by respective sectoral output x i as

b i = e i x i
(12)

Subscript i denotes the element in row of the matrix. From (12), a change in output Δx (estimated with Eq. (11)) would result in a change of environmental and socioeconomic factors and could be calculated as

Δe= b ˆ Δx
(13)

where Δe is a vector of change in resource inputs or emissions, b ˆ is the diagonal matrix of physical coefficients.

3.3 Data

The most recent input–output table for Ukraine, available for 2008 is used in this study (SSCU [2010]). In the columns of the table, industry sectors are classified according to Ukrainian statistical classification of economic activities, which was developed based on classification of economic activities in the European Community (NACE). Classification of commodities and services (in rows of the table) is in line with state classification of commodities and services based on European Classification of Products by Activity (CPA).

The table consists of 38 sectors, 6 of which refer to energy goods and services, 11 manufacturing industries and construction, 16 service sectors, 2 transport sectors and communications, 3 sectors capture activities in agriculture, fishing and forestry. Table 2 illustrates interindustry transactions between sectors (Z), final demand for each industry’s outputs (x) is reflected in the column vector y and v refers to primary inputs required by each sector. Value added part of the table incorporates wages for employees, profits, taxes, and subsidies on production. In addition to final deliveries to households, government and nonprofit institutions, the “use” section of the table provides data on gross capital formation and net exports.

Table 2 Schematic representation of the IO table

The table is augmented by additional columns in physical units to account for effects on GHG emissions, employment, total energy and gas consumption by each sector utilizing the data published by the State Statistics Committee of Ukraine ([2009a, 2009b, 2009c]) and GHG emissions inventory of Ukraine (MENR [2010]). Since the level of detail for each examined variable is different, the table has been aggregated to complement the data on environmental and socioeconomic factors. In particular, the table was aggregated to 13 economic sectors to complement GHG emissions data available and to 28 sectors to study effects on energy consumption and employment.

3.4 Limitations

It is important to note that obtained results should be treated with caution because of the data caveats associated with this study and inherent limitations of the methods used. First of all, the accuracy of obtained results depends on the quality of the data used in the model. National income accounts always have a “residual error,” which is the difference of GDP estimates according to two of three possible conventions (Perman et al. [2003]). Secondly, input–output models embody a number of simplifying assumptions, which should be considered carefully while interpreting obtained results. However, those assumptions are transparent and mathematically traceable. One of the most important shortcomings of the input–output analytical framework is that technical coefficients and the coefficients of physical factors, e.g., GHG emissions and energy inputs do not change as a result of energy subsidy induced price changes. In other words, there are no substitution responses to increased prices of energy inputs. At the same time, price elasticities of demand are incorporated in the study design to allow for adjustment of quantities of goods consumed to price changes. Ho et al. ([2008]) argue that this approach could be intrinsically inconsistent since the response of final consumers to higher prices is taken into an account while producers are not able to switch to less energy intensive inputs. Therefore, an assumption is made that all additional costs to producers are passed on to final consumers. In addition, Perman et al. ([2003]) note that, in reality, higher energy prices would result in consumption of less energy per unit of output and less energy-intensive intermediate inputs, which in turn would decrease prices. Thus, the input–output price model sets up the upper margins to price changes which would eventually occur. Moreover, there are some other important limitations of using input–output analysis. In particular, price changes would also affect investment decisions and labor inputs, which are not taken into account (Ho et al. [2008]). Nevertheless, assumptions of the approach are consistent with the short-term time framework adopted in the analysis. In other words, the impacts of subsidy reform are estimated before the economy has adjusted for price changes assuming that there is no time for structural changes and substitution of labor and capital for energy as well as cross-substitution of fuels. Technological change and cross-substitution between energy and nonenergy factors of production could be explicitly modeled with (CGE) models, which on the other hand introduce other model-immanent problems (see, e.g., Clarete and Roumasset [1986]; Scrieciu [2007]). Other methodological limitations are highlighted in the analysis section since they are important for interpretation of estimates obtained.

4 Results and Discussion

4.1 Energy Subsidies in the Gas and Electricity Sectors of Ukraine

We evaluated consumer subsidies for gas and electricity sectors utilizing the price gap approach, which is described in detail in the Methodology section. Estimated reference prices that would prevail in an “ideal” market (where all subsidies are eliminated) are significantly higher than current prices for gas and electricity (see Table 3).

Table 3 Comparison of actual (average for 2008) and reference prices for gas and electricity

Retail gas prices for households and district heating companies constitute only 26 % and 57 % of the reference price, respectively. In comparison, current prices for industry and state-funded institutions are equal to 81 % of the reference price because tariffs for these consumer groups are based on the import gas price. It is important to note that the estimate is highly sensitive to the import border price. The price of Russian gas for Ukraine is indexed to prices of oil products at the global market and also depends on the political situation between two countries. Hence, it is likely that the gas price will continue to grow in the future and domestic gas tariffs should be increased in line with import gas prices to prevent price distortions in the domestic market.

Electricity prices for all consumer groups are significantly lower than the reference price. Tariffs should be increased by about two times the current level for nonresidential consumers and almost three times for households in order to reflect long-run production cost. Interestingly, the estimated reference price is still lower than the electricity tariffs for households in most EU countries. In particular, the reference price of 615.7 UAH/MWh equals 0.064 EUR/kWh. In comparison, the lowest electricity tariff for households (at annual consumption 3500 kWh) was in Latvia, 0.068 EUR/kWh, and the highest in Italy, 0.268 EUR/kWh as of July, 2010 (Europe’s Energy Portal [2010]).

Following the price-gap approach described in the Methodology section (see Eqs. (1)–(4)), we found that implicit subsidies at 2008-consumption levels amounted to almost 26 billion UAH (5 billion USD) in the gas sector and approximately 24 billion UAH (4.6 billion USD) in the electricity sector. It should be noted that estimates obtained represent a lower margin for subsidies in the sector since underpriced fuel inputs such as gas and coal are not taken into an account. Interestingly, IEA ([2011b]) estimates of subsidies differ significantly (8.27 billion USD and 1.51 billion USD for gas and electricity sector, respectively). Although the study adopted the IEA methodology ([1999, 2006a, 2006b, 2008]), obtained results are not directly comparable with estimates provided in the Fossil fuel subsidy database (IEA [2011b]) because it is not clear what assumptions have been used for estimation of the reference prices.

End-user subsidies in gas and electricity sectors are equal to 2.7 % and 2.6 % of the GDP, respectively, and cumulatively comparable to approximately 16 % of the state budget.Footnote 3 However, it is essential to point out that these estimates do not reflect direct state transfers to the energy sector and only capture market interventions resulted in decreased prices for final consumers. In comparison, direct financial support to oil and gas extraction sector and electricity production recorded in the IO table roughly equals 2.2 billion UAH (0.4 billion USD) and 1.3 billion UAH (0.3 billion USD), respectively (SSCU [2010]).

4.2 Effects on Relative Prices, Production and Employment

This study explores effects of rapid price rises for gas and electricity as a result of a hypothetical elimination of implicit subsidies in these sectors. In fact, this would lead to a fourfold increase of the gas price for households to reflect true opportunity cost of domestically produced gas and an increase of the electricity price of around three times to ensure compensation for long-run production costs. It is important to note, however, that these scenarios are hypothetical and the government is advised to increase prices gradually to mitigate negative economic and social effects. Unlike the IER ([2006, 2007]) studies, this paper investigates short-term effects of price shocks assuming that economy does not have enough time to allow for restructuring and substitution between energy and nonenergy factors of production. It is estimated that price increases for gas and electricity of 1.43 UAH per m3 (0.27 USD per m3) and 0.62 UAH/kWh (0.12 USD/kWh) would more than double relative prices for some industries while prices of others are not considerably affected. Interestingly, prices in oil and gas extraction and electricity production sectors have increased less than in some other industries. Figure 1 illustrates the increase in relative prices for most affected sectors (see Additional file 1, Table A.1 for breakdown of price changes for all sectors). A group of sectors in supply and distribution of gas, electricity, and water are likely to experience the highest increase of relative prices. This could be explained by large input requirements for gas and electricity per unit of output. Assuming that all price shocks are passed on to final consumers, relative prices of services of the water purification and distribution, for example, would rise by about 40 % and about 180 %, respectively, as a result of price hikes in gas and electricity sectors. Other highly impacted sectors are forestry, mining of nonenergy materials and several manufacturing sectors, particularly the manufacture of coke products and manufacture of other nonmetallic mineral products.

Fig. 1
figure 1

Increase of relative prices for different economic sectors

Steep price increases for commodities of different sectors are likely to enforce knock-on effects on final demand for these products since consumers would seek to minimize their losses by introducing energy saving measures or switching to less energy-intensive goods. However, demand sensitivity is likely to be inelastic in the short-term for most sectors. We found that examined price shocks could cumulatively result in reduction of total final demand by about 2.5 % or around 18.7 billion UAH (3.6 billion USD) (see Additional file 1, Table A.1 for results for all sectors). Assuming that investment and net exports do not change in the short-run a phasing out subsidies in the gas and electricity sectors could result in a decline of GDP by about 1.35 % and 0.62 %, respectively, relative to 2008 level. It should be noted that higher energy prices could bring higher revenues to the government in the form of tax payments. However, this effect may be counteracted by reduced consumption and production; in case the former effect will prevail and government revenue will still increase. For simplicity, this analysis assumes that the excess money will be spent to reduce foreign debt of Ukraine rather than a recycling back of revenues to consumers.

A drop in final demand would in turn lead to decline of production of energy-intensive sectors in the first place and would also have indirect effects on other industries. Utilizing the demand-driven IO model, we estimate that total output would decrease by about 1.8 % or 43 billion UAH. Figure 2 illustrates the breakdown of the percentage decline in gross output for all sectors.

Fig. 2
figure 2

Decline of production for different economic sectors

A decline of total production would lead to excess of labor per unit of output. Thus, producers would have to fire extra workers to minimize losses. It is estimated that the number of jobs would be reduced by 223 thousand or by 1.3 % and 0.7 % as a result of the removal of subsidies in gas and electricity sectors, respectively. Employment effects for each sector are determined by labor intensity and percentage decline in gross output. For example, service sectors (e.g., public administration, education, and health care) are the most labor-intensive sectors with up to 27 employees per million UAH of output in health care. However, a relatively low decline in total output would result in only 1–2 % decline in the number of jobs. In comparison, relatively low labor intensity in oil and gas extraction (about 4 workers per unit of output) coupled with a major decline in production, illustrated in Fig. 2, would result in a 22 % loss of jobs. Sectors in production and distribution of water and gas would be also highly affected due to large cuts in production.

Overall, an energy subsidy reform is likely to have negative effects on the total employment in the short-run. However, it is important to note that these estimates are the indication of the upper bound of employment effects considering uncertainty on adjustment of the production levels. Nevertheless, over a longer time horizon, the economy would restructure toward less energy-intensive sectors and reduced employment in the shrinking sectors is likely to be compensated by expanded production and new jobs in other industries. However, labor reallocation could not be modeled within the chosen IO framework.

4.3 Income Effects for Different Income Groups

We examine income distribution effects for households resulting from energy pricing policy reform in the gas and electricity sectors. The consumer price index reflects the cost of a standard basket of goods and services required by households for an everyday life, and hence, could be an appropriate measure for estimation of welfare effects of energy pricing policies. The overall effect is determined by the increase of relative prices for different economic sectors and structure of consumer expenditure for different income groups. Figure 3 illustrates increase of CPI or percentage of additional income required by rural and urban households for buying the same set of goods and services. Adjusting gas and electricity prices to market levels will reduce the real income and purchasing power by about 13.2 % for urban poor and by 11.5 % for higher income households. Rural families are comparatively less susceptible to an energy subsidy reform since utilities and housing related payments, which face the highest price increase, constitute a lower share of their monthly expenditures. In particular, urban families allocate between 7.7 % and 10.8 % of their budgets to utility payments while rural ones only allocate 4.2–6.4 % (SSCU [2009b]).

Fig. 3
figure 3

CPI increase for different socioeconomic groups of urban and rural households. Note: socioeconomic groups are ordered from lowest (1st) to highest income (11th)

It can be noted from Fig. 3 that an energy subsidy reform is likely to be regressive for urban but nonregressive for rural households. Interestingly, regressive effects are concealed if urban and rural households are aggregated (see Fig. 4). Both urban and rural families are more vulnerable to elimination of gas subsidies with Consumer Price Index (CPI) rising by 7.7 % for urban poor and by 6.4 % for higher income urban families. For rural households, these figures are 5.4 % and 4.6 %, respectively.

Fig. 4
figure 4

Increase of CPI differentiated between 9 aggregate consumption categories by socioeconomic groups. Note: (1) socioeconomic groups are ordered from lowest (1st) to highest (11th). (2) See Additional file 2, Table B.1. for compatibility of IO sectors with aggregate consumption categories

Figure 4 shows contribution of aggregate consumption categories to overall change of CPI for different income groups (rural and urban households are aggregated). Housing is largely responsible for the energy prices induced increase in the inflation rate. It constitutes 76 % for the lowest and 70 % for the highest income households in the cumulative CPI. Food and clothing, which also reflect basic necessities, follow a similar pattern with their CPI fractions being higher for the poor families and lower for higher income families. Other consumption categories, especially more luxury goods such as miscellaneous goods and restaurants and hotels depict quite an opposite situation with CPI shares being lower for poor households and higher for the ones with higher income.

It is important to note that estimated inflation rates represent the upper bounds of CPI changes because consumption patterns of households would change by shifting to comparable commodities for which prices had increased to a lesser extent, which in turn would reduce the CPI impact of eliminating subsidies. However, the IO model incorporates the assumption that household consumption patterns do not change in response to changes of relative prices of goods and services similar to constant technical coefficients (Perman et al. [2003]), which is a reasonable assumption for short-time horizons explored in this study.

It is interesting to compare an average estimated CPI for all households of 10.5 % (see Fig. 4) resulting from a hypothetical energy subsidies reform with the actual inflation rate at the same time, which amounted to 12.8 % and 25.2 % in 2007 and 2008, respectively (SSCU [2009a]). Therefore, it should be noted that immediate removal of energy subsidies and liberalization of energy prices at one step would not be tolerable to society considering already relatively high annual inflation rates observed in Ukraine. Hence, an increase of energy prices up to market levels should be implemented in steps and accompanied by social support programs targeting the most vulnerable households.

4.4 Effects on Energy Consumption

Elimination of energy subsidies in electricity and gas sectors is essential to decrease the energy-intensity of the economy of Ukraine, which is presently much higher than in developed counties (IEA [2011a]). This could be explained by a number of reasons including outdated technologies used in production processes and energy conversion (IEA [2006b]); however, cheap energy is one of the most important if not the primary determinant. A report by IEA ([1999]) presents evidence that there is a strong negative correlation between electricity prices and energy consumption per unit of GDP across 27 OECD and 22 non-OECD countries. Although other external drivers such as climate conditions, average distances, or population density might also come into play, such a strong inverse relationship between electricity use and prices could not be fully explained by structural parameters.

We found that a removal of the indirect gas and electricity subsidies would lead to a drop in total energy consumption by about 2.5 % (5 million tons of coal equivalentFootnote 4) in the short term (see Eq. (13) in Sect. 3), 68 % of this reduction was due to phasing out subsidies in the gas sector (see Additional file 1, Table A.3 for a breakdown of results for all sectors). Figure 5 shows the sectors that could generate the highest energy savings. In particular, the manufacture of coke and petroleum products could reduce energy consumption by more than 1 million tons of coal equivalent due to relatively high energy requirements per unit of output and a considerable decline in total production of the sector (see Fig. 5). However, in relative terms, this would mean only a 6 % decline in overall energy consumption of the sector. Significant amounts of energy could also be saved in the supply and distribution of gas, electricity, and water, which have the highest average energy-intensity of about 0.5 thousand tons of coal equivalent, followed by metallurgy, chemicals, and transportation.

Fig. 5
figure 5

Energy saved (in 1000 tons of coal equivalent) as a result of elimination of subsidies in gas and electricity sectors

It is important to note that obtained results are of indicative character and depend highly upon responsiveness of consumers to price changes and flexibility in production adjustments of economic sectors. Moreover, it should be noted that energy savings are caused by demand-induced decline in total production and not because of technological change since significant efficiency improvements are not feasible in the short-term and, therefore, ignored in this analysis (see the Sect. 3.2.3 for more detail). Over the longer-term, however, price signals could stimulate energy efficiency improvements and development of less energy-intensive industries.

Since energy security is of big concern for Ukraine as a net-importer of gas (domestic production could satisfy only about 20 % of the demand (IEA [2006b])), it is also of interest to examine short-term effects of the subsidy reform on total gas consumption. Figure 6 illustrates sectors that could bring the highest decline in gas use (see Additional file 1, Table A.3 for a breakdown of results for all sectors). Sectors in hot water supply and electricity production are likely to contribute 21 % and 19 % of the total decline in gas consumption, respectively. Chemicals and plastics would also reduce gas use considerably due to high requirement for gas inputs in production.

Fig. 6
figure 6

Reduction in gas consumption in different economic sectors

Overall, elimination of subsidies in the gas and electricity sectors would bring reductions of about 3.6 % in total gas consumption which equals roughly 1.6 billion m3. However, considering the long-term nature of interstate gas contracts, it is not likely that Ukraine could reduce gas imports in the short-term. Obtained figures rather serve as an indication of potential gas savings if energy pricing policy is improved and final consumers are required to pay the real cost of gas and electricity. Although in the short-term gas use would decline solely because of drop in final demand and GDP, price stimuli are essential to trigger energy efficiency improvements, which could bring even larger savings in the future without adverse impacts on the GDP growth. For example, Flanagan et al. ([2007]) utilize a semistructural approach to examine the role of efficiency in mitigating negative impacts of energy price shocks. Assuming 3 % of GDP for intermediate energy consumption, the authors have estimated that negative impacts of a 10 % increase of the import gas price could be completely offset by 9 % improvement in gas efficiency.

4.5 Effects on GHG Emissions

We estimate that elimination of energy subsidies in gas and electricity sectors would result in a reduction of about 15 million tons of CO2-eq. or a 3.6 % reduction of total GHG emissions of Ukraine. Figure 7 illustrates each sector’s share in total GHG emissions reductions (see also Additional file 1, Table A.4 for a breakdown of results for all sectors). Although estimated energy subsidies are of similar magnitude in both sectors, removal of subsidies in the gas sector has a significantly larger effect on emissions reductions.

Fig. 7
figure 7

Emission reductions (in 1000 tons CO2-eq.) in each sector as a result of elimination of gas and electricity subsidies

This could be explained by the fact that estimated subsidies are much higher than the present value added of the gas sector of about 7 billion UAH (1.3 billion USD) compared to value added of the electricity sector of about 23 billion UAH (4.4 billion USD). Hence, elimination of subsidies would result in higher prices for gas, which in turn would have a larger effect on relative prices, final demand, and output of other sectors. The largest share of emissions reductions would be observed in the oil and gas extraction sectors due to a decline of fugitive methane emissions. Energy supply and distribution sectors are also likely to deliver considerable emission cuts with reductions in electricity production and hot water supply of about 10 % and 16 %, respectively. GHG emissions from fuel combustion by households would be 15 % lower.

It is important to note that cross-substitution between different fuels is not considered in this paper. It is a major limitation for evaluation of impacts on GHG emissions since higher prices for one type of fuel could stimulate end-users to substitute for cheaper ones in the long run. Subsidies for coal are beyond the scope of this paper; however, coal is the most carbon-intensive fuel. If end-user subsidies are eliminated only in gas and electricity sectors and coal prices remain at below market levels (due to producer subsidies), both end-users and intermediate consumers, e.g., power plants are likely to switch to coal as less expensive energy source as much as technological capacity would allow. In this case, liberalization of gas and electricity prices would likely result in larger coal use and higher GHG emissions. Hence, energy subsidy reform should consider all fuels to prevent undesirable effects. Moreover, depending on the resultant market price of different fuels an additional measure might be required to prevent substitution for coal, e.g., carbon tax charged depending on the carbon-intensity of the output.

5 Conclusions

This paper has adopted the price-gap approach for estimation of indirect end-user subsidies in gas and electricity sectors in Ukraine and considered a hypothetical elimination of energy subsidies. Although a minor decline in GDP is expected, this is the short-term price to be paid to correct market distortions that had been accumulated over decades of inefficient energy pricing. Other benefits of the removal of subsidies would include a reduction in total energy consumption and GHG emissions, which would drop by about 2.5 % and 3.6 %, respectively. In addition, these short-term demand-induced effects would potentially trigger dynamic effects of accelerated technological improvements over the long term.

Energy subsidy reform is likely to have negative employment effects due to steep production cuts in resource-intensive sectors. However, a short-term loss of jobs could be minimized if the government would create favorable conditions for the establishment of new working places in other sectors. Removal of subsidies is also likely to be regressive with lower income groups, who spend a larger share of their income on fuels, to be affected more than richer households. However, this effect could be mitigated by social policies targeting the most vulnerable.

It is important to note that complete and immediate elimination of subsidies is considered here as a theoretical exercise and is done to provide an estimate of potential losses and negative social effects. A gradual phase-out is more advisable to mitigate negative effects. In addition, end-user subsidies reform in gas and electricity sectors is not sufficient to correct all price distortions. Producer subsidies in the coal sector should be also eliminated to stimulate technological change toward a less carbon-intensive economy and to avoid switching to cheaper coal. Moreover, obtained results are of an indicative character due to data caveats and other shortcomings of the methods applied, and only illustrate the magnitude of the likely effects of subsidy reform in the short-run. Nevertheless, even rough quantitative estimates could be useful for decision-makers since they provide valuable insights for the planning of energy and climate policy of Ukraine.

Electronic Supplementary Material

Notes

  1. Decree of Cabinet of Ministers of Ukraine N 442 as of 11 June 2005 on the special surcharge on gas tariff.

  2. Decree of Cabinet of Ministers of Ukraine N 163 as of 5 March 2008 on selling imported natural gas in Ukraine.

  3. In 2008, GDP was at the level of 949864 million UAH (180336 million USD) and budget expenditure was 312018 million UAH (59238 million USD) (SSCU [2009a]).

  4. Coal equivalent instead of oil equivalent is usually used in Ukraine. Coal equivalent could be converted to oil equivalent by multiplying the former by 0.7.

References

  1. Andrikopoulos AA, Brox JA, Georgakopoulos TA: Short-run expenditure and price elasticities for agricultural commodities: the case of Greece, 1951–1983. Eur Rev Agric Econ 1987, 14: 335–346. 10.1093/erae/14.3.335

    Article  Google Scholar 

  2. Atakanova Z, Howie P: Electricity demand in Kazakhstan. Energy Policy 2007, 35: 3729–3743. 10.1016/j.enpol.2007.01.005

    Article  Google Scholar 

  3. Bentzen J, Engsted T: Short- and long-run elasticities in energy demand: a cointegration approach. Energy Econ 1993, 15: 9–16. 10.1016/0140-9883(93)90037-R

    Article  Google Scholar 

  4. Bernstein MA, Griffin J (2006) Regional differences in the price-elasticity of demand for energy. National Renewable Energy Laboratory. Available via DIALOG. http://www.nrel.gov/docs/fy06osti/39512.pdf. Accessed 25 Aug 2012.

  5. Bohi DR: On the macroeconomic effects of energy price shocks. Resour Energy 1991, 13: 145–162. 10.1016/0165-0572(91)90012-R

    Article  Google Scholar 

  6. Burniaux J-M, Martin JP, Olivera-Martins J (1992) The effect of existing distortions in energy markets on the costs of policies to reduce CO2 emissions: evidence from GREEN. Available via DIALOG. http://www.oecd.org/eco/productivityandlongtermgrowth/35044850.pdf. Accessed 25 Aug 2012.

  7. Burniaux J-M, Chateau J, Dellink R, Duval R, Jamet S (2009) The economics of climate change mitigation: how to build the necessary global action in a cost-effective manner? Available via DIALOG. http://www.oecd.org/officialdocuments/displaydocumentpdf?cote=ECO/WKP%282009%2942&doclanguage=en. Accessed 25 Aug 2012.

  8. Choi J, Bakshi BR, Haab T: Effects of a carbon price in the U.S. on economic sectors, resource use, and emissions: an input–output approach. Energy Policy 2010, 38: 3527–3536. 10.1016/j.enpol.2010.02.029

    Article  Google Scholar 

  9. Cohn SM: Fuel choice and aggregate energy demand in the residential and commercial sectors. Energy 1980, 5: 1203–1212. 10.1016/0360-5442(80)90062-6

    Article  Google Scholar 

  10. Clarete RL, Roumasset JA: CGE models and development policy analysis: problems, pitfalls, and challenges. Am J Agric Econ 1986, 68: 1212–1216. 10.2307/1241877

    Article  Google Scholar 

  11. Corden M: The calculation of the cost of protection. Econ Rec 1957, 33: 29–51. 10.1111/j.1475-4932.1957.tb01273.x

    Article  Google Scholar 

  12. Dodonov B, Opitz P, Pfaffenberger W: How much do electricity tariff increases in Ukraine hurt the poor? Energy Policy 2004, 32: 855–863. 10.1016/S0301-4215(03)00012-0

    Article  Google Scholar 

  13. EBRD (2011) Residential sector of Ukraine: legal, regulatory, institutional, technical and financial considerations. Available via DIALOG. http://www.teplydim.com.ua/static/storage/files/files/Market_Assessment_Report_Final_Eng_Sep-2011.pdf. Accessed 21 Aug 2013.

  14. Ellis J (2010) The effects of fossil-fuel subsidy reform: a review of modeling and empirical studies. Global Subsidies Initiative. Available via DIALOG. http://www.globalsubsidies.org/files/assets/effects_ffs.pdf. Accessed 25 Aug 2012.

  15. Europe’s Energy Portal (2010) Domestic electricity and gas prices. http://www.energy.eu. Accessed 30 July 2010.

  16. Fankhauser S, Tepic S: Can poor consumers pay for energy and water? An affordability analysis for transition countries. Energy Policy 2007, 35: 1038–1049. 10.1016/j.enpol.2006.02.003

    Article  Google Scholar 

  17. Fankhauser S, Rodionova Y, Falcetti E: Utility payments in Ukraine: affordability, subsidies and arrears. Energy Policy 2008, 36: 4168–4177. 10.1016/j.enpol.2008.06.031

    Article  Google Scholar 

  18. Feng K, Hubacek K, Guan D, Contestabile M, Minx J, Barrett J: Distributional effects of climate change taxation: the case of the UK. Environ Sci Technol 2010, 44: 3670–3676. 10.1021/es902974g

    Article  Google Scholar 

  19. Flanagan M, Schaechter A, Chelsky J, Gonzalez M, Halikias I, Ribakova E (2007) Ukraine: selected issues. International Monetary Fund. Available via DIALOG. http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/scr/2007/cr0747.pdf. Accessed 25 Aug 2012.

  20. Gangopadhyay S, Ramaswami B, Wadhwa W: Reducing subsidies on household fuels in India: how will it affect the poor? Energy Policy 2005, 33: 2326–2336. 10.1016/j.enpol.2004.04.024

    Article  Google Scholar 

  21. Ginsburgh V, Keyzer M: The structure of applied general equilibrium models. MIT Press, Cambridge; 1997.

    Google Scholar 

  22. Ho MS, Morgenstern R, Shih J (2008) Impact of carbon price policies on U.S. industry. Resources for the Future. Available via DIALOG. http://www.rff.org/rff/documents/rff-dp-08–37.pdf. Accessed 25 Aug 2012.

  23. IEA: World energy outlook insights, looking at energy subsidies: getting the prices right. OECD Publishing, Paris; 1999.

    Google Scholar 

  24. IEA: Analysis of the impact of high oil prices on the global economy. OECD Publishing, Paris; 2004.

    Google Scholar 

  25. IEA: World energy outlook. OECD Publishing, Paris; 2006.

    Google Scholar 

  26. IEA: Ukraine: energy policy review. OECD Publishing, Paris; 2006.

    Google Scholar 

  27. IEA: World energy outlook. OECD Publishing, Paris; 2008.

    Google Scholar 

  28. IEA: Key world energy statistics. OECD Publishing, Paris; 2011.

    Google Scholar 

  29. IEA (2011b) Fossil fuel subsidy database. www.iea.org/subsidy/index.html. Accessed 25 Aug 2012.

  30. IEA: Ukraine 2012: energy policies beyond IEA countries. IEA Publications, Paris; 2012.

    Google Scholar 

  31. IER (2006) Macroeconomic impact of gas price shock. Available via DIALOG. http://www.ier.com.ua/files/publications/Policy_papers/German_advisory_group/2006/V5_eng.pdf. Accessed 25 Aug 2012.

  32. IER (2007) Energy price shocks and market reforms: a quantitative assessment. Available via DIALOG. http://www.beratergruppe-ukraine.de/download/Beraterpapiere/2007/w3_en_Pavel_Energy%20price%20shocks.pdf. Accessed 25 Aug 2012.

  33. ILO: Consumer price index manual: theory and practice. International Labour Office, Geneva; 2004.

    Google Scholar 

  34. Kebede B: Energy subsidies and costs in urban Ethiopia: the cases of kerosene and electricity. Renew Energy 2006, 31: 2140–2151. 10.1016/j.renene.2005.10.005

    Article  Google Scholar 

  35. Kerkhof AC, Moll HC, Drissen E, Wilting HC: Taxation of multiple greenhouse gases and the effects on income distribution: a case study of the Netherlands. Ecol Econ 2008, 67: 318–326. 10.1016/j.ecolecon.2007.12.015

    Article  Google Scholar 

  36. Koplow D (2009) Measuring energy subsidies using the price-gap approach: what does it leave out? International Institute for Sustainable Development. Available via DIALOG. http://www.iisd.org/pdf/2009/bali_2_copenhagen_ff_subsidies_pricegap.pdf. Accessed 25 Aug 2012.

  37. Lampietti J, Meyer A (2002) Coping with the cold, heating strategies for Eastern Europe and Central Asia’s urban poor. Technical paper 529, World Bank, Washington, DC Lampietti J, Meyer A (2002) Coping with the cold, heating strategies for Eastern Europe and Central Asia’s urban poor. Technical paper 529, World Bank, Washington, DC

  38. Lampietti J, Kolb A, Gulyani S, Avenesyan V (2001) Utility pricing and the poor, lessons from Armenia. Technical paper 497, World Bank, Washington, DC Lampietti J, Kolb A, Gulyani S, Avenesyan V (2001) Utility pricing and the poor, lessons from Armenia. Technical paper 497, World Bank, Washington, DC

  39. Lardic S, Mignon V: The impact of oil prices on GDP in European countries: an empirical investigation based on asymmetric cointegration. Energy Policy 2006, 34: 3910–3915. 10.1016/j.enpol.2005.09.019

    Article  Google Scholar 

  40. Larsen B, Shah A (1992) World energy subsidies and global carbon emissions. Research paper 1002, World Bank. Available via DIALOG. http://info.worldbank.org/etools/docs/library/206933/WorldFossilFuelSubsidiesandGlobalCarbonEmissions.pdf. Accessed 25 Aug 2012.

  41. Legeida N (2001) Implicit subsidies in Ukraine: estimation, developments and policy implications. Institute for Economic Research and Policy Consulting. Available via DIALOG. http://www.ier.com.ua/files/publications/WP/2001/Wp10_eng.pdf. Accessed 25 Aug 2012.

  42. Lin B, Jiang Z: Estimates of energy subsidies in China and impact of energy subsidy reform. Energy Econ 2011, 33: 273–283. 10.1016/j.eneco.2010.07.005

    Article  Google Scholar 

  43. Lovei L, Gurenko E, Haney M, O’Keefe P, Shkaratan M: Maintaining utility services for the poor: policies and practices in Central and Eastern Europe and the former Soviet Union. World Bank, Washington; 2000.

    Google Scholar 

  44. Miller RE, Blair PD: Input–output analysis: foundations and extensions. 2nd edition. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge; 2009.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  45. MENR (2010) National inventory of anthropogenic GHGs emissions and absorption. Available via DIALOG. http://unfccc.int/files/national_reports/annex_i_ghg_inventories/national_inventories_submissions/application/zip/ukr-2011-nir-08jun.zip. Accessed 25 Aug 2012.

  46. MFE (2006) Energy strategy of Ukraine by 2030. Available via DIALOG. http://mpe.kmu.gov.ua/fuel/control/uk/doccatalog/list?currDir=50505. Accessed 25 Aug 2012.

  47. MFE (2009) Annual report on development of fuel and energy complex of Ukraine. Available via DIALOG. http://mpe.kmu.gov.ua/fuel/control/uk/publish/article?art_id=146539&cat_id=35081. Accessed 6 Oct 2011 (in Ukrainian).

  48. Nahata B, Izyumov A, Busygin A, Mishura A: Application of Ramsey model in transition economy: a Russian case study. Energy Econ 2007, 29: 105–125. 10.1016/j.eneco.2005.09.011

    Article  Google Scholar 

  49. Nasseh AR, Elyasiani E: Energy price shocks in the 1970s: impact on industrialized economies. Energy Econ 1984, 6: 231–244. 10.1016/0140-9883(84)90002-1

    Article  Google Scholar 

  50. National Bank of Ukraine (2011) Official exchange rate of UAH (average for period). Available via DIALOG. http://www.bank.gov.ua/Statist/Stat_data/Exchange_r.xls. Accessed 30 July 2011.

  51. NERC (2009) Annual report of National Electricity Regulation Commission: 2008. Available via DIALOG. http://www2.nerc.gov.ua/control/uk/publish/article/main?art_id=81662&cat_id=34446. Accessed 6 Oct 2011 (in Ukrainian).

  52. OECD (2007) Financing water supply and sanitation in EECCA countries and progress in achieving the water-related millennium development goals. Available via DIALOG. http://www.oecd.org/env/outreach/39174956.pdf. Accessed 25 Aug 2012.

  53. OECD (2010) Analysis of the scope of energy subsidies and suggestions for the G-20 Initiative. Background paper to the joint report by IEA, OPEC, OECD and World Bank. Available via DIALOG. http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/62/63/45339216.pdf. Accessed 25 Aug 2012.

  54. Parvin S, Banouei AA (2009) Assessing the susceptibility of elimination in energy subsidies on the living standards of households in Iran. 17th International Input Output Conference, São Paulo, July 13–17. Available via DIALOG. http://www.iioa.org/conferences/17th/papers/622597991_090620_071301_PARVINANDBANOUEI.PDF. Accessed 25 Aug 2012.

  55. Perman R, Ma Y, Common M, Maddison D, Mcqilvray J: Natural resource and environmental economics. 3rd edition. Pearson Education, Glasgow; 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  56. Petri M, Taube G, Tsyvinski A (2002) Energy sector quasi-fiscal activities in the countries of the former Soviet Union. Working paper, IMF. Available via DIALOG. http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/wp/2002/wp0260.pdf. Accessed 25 Aug 2012.

  57. Pirani S (2007) Ukraine’s gas sector. Oxford Institute for Energy Studies. Available via DIALOG. http://www.oxfordenergy.org/wpcms/wp-content/uploads/2010/11/NG21-UkrainesGasSector-SimonPirani-2007.pdf. Accessed 25 Aug 2012.

  58. Prosser RD: Demand elasticities in OECD: dynamical aspects. Energy Econ 1985, 7: 9–12. 10.1016/0140-9883(85)90033-7

    Article  Google Scholar 

  59. Russo C, Green RD, Howitt RE (2008) Estimation of supply and demand elasticities of California commodities. Department of Agricultural and Resource, Economics, UCD, UC Davis. Available via DIALOG. http://escholarship.org/uc/item/3432z1pv. Accessed 25 Aug 2012.

  60. Saavalainen T, Berge J (2006) Quasi-fiscal deficits and energy conditionality in selected CIS countries. Working paper 06/43, International Monetary Fund. Available via DIALOG. http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/wp/2006/wp0643.pdf. Accessed 25 Aug 2012.

  61. Saboohi Y: An evaluation of the impact of reducing energy subsidies on living expenses of households. Energy Policy 2001, 29: 245–252. 10.1016/S0301-4215(00)00116-6

    Article  Google Scholar 

  62. Saunders M, Schneider K (2000) Removing energy subsidies in developing and transition economies. ABARE Conference paper 2000.14. 23rd Annual IAEE International Conference, International Association of Energy Economics, Sydney, June 7–10. Available via DIALOG. http://www.earthtrack.net/files/Saunders_Schneider.pdf. Accessed 25 Aug 2012.

  63. Scrieciu SS: The inherent dangers of using computable general equilibrium models as a single integrated modeling framework for sustainability impact assessment. A critical note on Bohringer and Loschel (2006). Ecol Econ 2007, 60: 678. 10.1016/j.ecolecon.2006.09.012

    Article  Google Scholar 

  64. Soheir A, El-Laithy H, Kheir-El-Din H (2009) The impact of phasing out subsidies of petroleum energy products in Egypt. The Egyptian Center for Economic Studies. Available via DIALOG. http://www.eces.org.eg/Uploaded_Files/%7B87C87F1A-6C8D-4A4D-BC46–18C15168AF13%7D_ECES%20WP145.pdf. Accessed 25 Aug 2012.

  65. SSCU: Statistical yearbook of Ukraine for 2008. SSCU, Kyiv; 2009. (in Ukrainian) (in Ukrainian)

    Google Scholar 

  66. SSCU: Household income and expenditures in Ukraine for 2008. SSCU, Kyiv; 2009. (in Ukrainian) (in Ukrainian)

    Google Scholar 

  67. SSCU: Fuel and energy resources of Ukraine. SSCU, Kyiv; 2009. (in Ukrainian) (in Ukrainian)

    Google Scholar 

  68. SSCU: Ukraine’s input–output table at consumer prices for 2008. SSCU, Kyiv; 2010.

    Google Scholar 

  69. UNEP (2004) Energy subsidies: lessons learned in assessing their impact and designing policy reforms. Available via DIALOG. http://www.unep.ch/etb/publications/energySubsidies/Energysubreport.pdf. Accessed 25 Aug 2012.

  70. United Nations Statistics Division (2010) Carbon dioxide emissions. http://mdgs.un.org/unsd/mdg/SeriesDetail.aspx?srid=749&crid=. Accessed 25 Aug 2012.

  71. Wohlgemuth N: World transport energy demand modeling: methodology and elasticities. Energy Policy 1997, 25: 1109–1119. 10.1016/S0301-4215(97)00103-1

    Article  Google Scholar 

  72. World Bank: Expanding the measure of wealth: indicators of environmentally sustainable development. World Bank, Washington; 1997.

    Google Scholar 

  73. World Bank (2005) Ukraine: the impact of higher natural gas and oil prices. Available via DIALOG. http://siteresources.worldbank.org/INTECAREGTOPENERGY/34004325–1112025344408/20772964/UkraineEnergyPricePolicyNote.pdf. Accessed 25 Aug 2012.

  74. World Bank (2012) Modernization of the district heating systems in Ukraine: heat metering and consumption-based billing. Report 64989-UA, Sustainable Development Department Europe and Central Asia Region. Available via DIALOG. http://siteresources.worldbank.org/UKRAINEINUKRAINIANEXTN/Resources/455680–1332179461564/UkraineDHreport2012e.pdf. Accessed 1 June 2013.

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Iuliia Ogarenko.

Additional information

Competing Interests

The authors declare that they have no competing interests.

Electronic supplementary material

Authors’ original submitted files for images

Rights and permissions

Open Access This article is distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 2.0 International License (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/2.0), which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Ogarenko, I., Hubacek, K. Eliminating Indirect Energy Subsidies in Ukraine: Estimation of Environmental and Socioeconomic Effects Using Input–Output Modeling. Economic Structures 2, 7 (2013). https://doi.org/10.1186/2193-2409-2-7

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1186/2193-2409-2-7

Keywords