Skip to main content

The Official Journal of the Pan-Pacific Association of Input-Output Studies (PAPAIOS)

Financial intermediaries and speculation in the foreign exchange market: the role of monetary policy in Iran’s economy

Abstract

Given the high fluctuations of the general price level, the importance of investment, and accessing sufficient financial resources, we examine the effects of monetary policy on the nominal (Inflation) and real (Investment) sectors of a developing economy, like Iran, through the channel of the relationship between bank deposits, stock market, and speculation in the foreign exchange market (FEM). For this purpose, due to regime switching in Iran’s economy, the non-linear relation between the variables has been investigated by applying Markov switching models and annual data of 1988–2018. The results show that the financial intermediaries (FIs) have not had a complementary relationship in both bear and bull market and high and low banks deposits regimes. Both FIs have negatively impacted speculation in the FEM in high and low exchange rates difference regimes. The difference between official and unofficial exchange rates negatively impacted the FIs in bear market and low banks deposits regimes; on the contrary, a positive effect in a bull market and high bank deposits. The effects of both FIs on investment have been positive in high and low investment regimes and negative on inflation rates in high and very high inflation regimes. In comparison, the impact of speculation in the FEM has been negative on investment and positive on inflation. Therefore, in the event of the lack of limitations regarding using interest rate (IR) and the policy of exchange rate unification, the central bank would be able to affect the nominal and real sectors of the economy suitably through the channels of the FIs and the FEM.

1 Introduction

The main objectives of the monetary policy are concentrated on affecting the stability of the inflation rate and the production conditions (Walsh 2010). In addition, the foreign exchange rate plays a vital role in some economies. More specifically, due to its effects on the firms’ products and input price, it can potentially influence the nominal (inflation) and real (investment and economic growth) sectors of an economy (Bahmani-Oskooee and Saha 2016). Hence, another monetary policy aim is affecting the foreign exchange rate (Senay and Sutherland 2019). On the other hand, the FIs can potentially affect real sectors of an economy due to their roles in financing investment through mobilizing resources (Levine 2005; McKinnon 1982; Seven and Yetkiner 2016; Greenbaum et al. 2019).

Moreover, whether the FIs can be a hedge for reduction of money value or not (Li, Narayan and Zheng 2010) has been a controversial issue for decades. Therefore, the monetary policy, the FEM, and the FIs could have some common impacts. Accordingly, there is a strong link between monetary policy, the FEM, and the FIs. In other words, the effects of monetary policy can be transmitted to nominal and real sectors of an economy by the channel of the FIs (Beck et al. 2014; Terra and Arestis 2017) and the FEM. One of the monetary instruments which can realize this link between the FIs, the FEM, and Monetary policy is IR.

The success of monetary policy in reaching its aims through the FIs and the FEM depends on which financial market will absorb further liquidity. It might influence the nominal and real economic indicators differently if the liquidity direction is toward the stock market, Bank deposits, or speculation in the FEM. Attracting liquidity by the FIs depends on the factors, such as inflation and the measure of risk. On this basis, increasing or at least keeping the value of different assets causes the investors to choose the FIs or the other financial markets based on their potentials. Bank deposits and the stock market have enough potential to be in the circle of investor’s choices. However, investing in bank deposits might encounter the risk of value lowering due to the negative real interest rate (RIR) originating from high inflation and repression of nominal interest rate (NIR). On the other hand, even with the attractiveness of the stock market to investors in the inflationary conditions due to growth of firms’ products price, it might also face the risk of increasing input price and, therefore, going up their costs. In brief, foreseeing the profitability outlook of firms would be difficult for investors in such a situation. Another critical point is that holding cash might have almost gotten out of investors’ choice because of decreasing its value over time due to the probable inflationary environment.

The exchange rate volatility can negatively affect investment by creating speculative activities and increasing uncertainty (Singleton 1987). The speculative activities in some financial markets might be a substitute for the FIs in attracting liquidity (Allen and Gale 1997). In this respect, given the fixed exchange rate and the high share of oil and its derivatives exports in the whole foreign currency reserves, the power of Iran’s Central Bank to support the aimed exchange rate through supplying foreign currency proportional with demand level is affected by negative oil shocks. In particular, the severe reduction in foreign currency reserves due to the USA sanctions has made many unwanted limitations for Iran’s Central Bank in providing enough supply. Hence, this matter creates enough conditions to form a gap between official and unofficial exchange rates. Therefore, in addition to high inflation, due to the gap between exchange rates, the FEM turned into a market where had enough potential to compete with the stock market and bank deposits for absorbing liquidity through the gains of speculation.

The inflation rate and investments in Iran’s economy have not shown a stable situation over the decades and have always faced high fluctuations. One of the factors that played a decisive role is cash flow. Due to remarkable capital gains of price fluctuations, liquidity has mainly been attracted by the markets whose goal is to obtain short-term profits from speculation. This issue has also affected financing the productive economic activities and the price level through creating false demands. In the developed economies, given the stability of general price level and its fluctuations in the determined range which sets and manages by central banks, the competition for attracting liquidity is mainly between bank deposits and the stock market; thus, the other markets are less attractive due to being low of capital gains from price fluctuations.

As discussed above, given the potential effects which IR has on the FEM, bank deposits, and loans, and consequently, the performance of firms listed on the stock market, it will also have the potential impacts on the central bank’s power to lead liquidity between the different financial markets in order to reach the monetary policy aims. In other words, the IR can fulfill the monetary policy aims by realizing the link between the FIs, the FEM, and monetary policy to transmit monetary policy effects to real and nominal sectors of the economy. However, Iran’s Central Bank has almost been passive against the high fluctuation of the inflation rate and the relationship between speculation in the FEM and the FIs due to repression of NIR (will be discussed in detail later).

Based on discussed cases, first sight concerning previous studies at this domain is that due to the stability of inflation rate in the developed and emerging economies, they have not paid enough attention to the probable relationship between the speculative activities in financial markets and the FIs and their competition over attracting liquidity in the countries where exists a high level of price fluctuations. The second is that they have not studied the role of monetary policy in leading liquidity between the FIs and speculation in other financial markets. Third, not considering these relations at different regimes. The last one is that no study has considered the mentioned entire cases simultaneously to reach more comparable and comprehensive results. Therefore, our contributions are to fade these gaps and add some valuations to existing studies.

Iran is a developing economy in which the central bank is not independent of the government’s fiscal policy and thus has faced limitations regarding financial resources due to the economic sanctions. In this respect, the debt volume of Iran’s government to central bank has been noticeably high. On the other hand, most firms have encountered insufficient financial resources, while the motivations of speculative activities have been high because of high fluctuation in some financial markets, like the FEM, at the same time. That is why the role of monetary policy in influencing the economy through the channel of financial markets to attract enough liquidity is considered essential. Hence, the main aim is to see whether the central bank and its monetary policy could affect the inflation and investment through the channel of the FEM and the FIs (leading liquidity between the aimed financial markets to transmit the effects of monetary policy to the nominal and real sectors of Iran’s economy). For this purpose, we are supposed to investigate whether there is a significant relationship between bank deposits, the stock market, and speculation in the FEM? How are these relations at different regimes? Is there competition between these markets in attracting liquidity, or is there a complementary relationship between them? How is the impact of every one of these markets on inflation and investment at different regimes? Given the repression of NIR and the inflationary environment of Iran’s economics, how is the effect of RIR on these markets and the relations between them?

The present paper is organized as follows: Section 2 discusses monetary policy in Iran’s economy. Section 3 pays attention to background literature. Section 4 assigns empirical model and specifying. The empirical results are paid by Sect. 5. Section 6 is devoted to discussion. The conclusions with policy implications are provided in Sect. 7.

2 Monetary policy in Iran’s economy

After a political revolution in 1979, due to the Islamic nature of the political movement, the economy was also affected. One of the most significant changes happened in the banking sector and monetary policy. In this regard, the ownership of most private banks was confiscated by the government. After that, given the high sensitivity of Islamic rules to the IR issue,Footnote 1 working on reformation of IR was started from the beginning of the new political regime in 1980. This reformation was eventually led to new legislation named “banking without free-interest rate.” Based on the legislation in 1984, all banks were pressured concerning the IR of deposits and loans. In addition to the banking sector, the central bank and its monetary policy were also influenced because of the limitation of using IR. However, the consequences of the legislation were revealed after the strange growth of the inflation rate and the lack of proportion between the inflation rate and the NIR of bank deposits and loans.

As presented in Table 1, the inflation rate has increased in most years after 1979 and 1984. On the other hand, due to the limitation of the central bank and banking sector in using IR, the central bank could not react to the inflation rate appropriately. Hence, there has not been a proportion between NIR and the inflation rate. The inflation rate has been more than the NIR of short-term bank deposits from the beginning of 1979. Therefore, the RIR of this kind of deposit has been negative except for 2015–2018. There have been the same conditions for the long-term deposits, except for 1986, 1991, 2001, 2002, 2006, 2007, 2010, 2011, and 2015–2018. The gap between the deposit interest rate and the inflation rate has considerably been high. See 1996 as the highest inflation rate (49.4%), the IR of short-term deposits did not change compared to two years ago (1994), while the inflation rate was doubled. On the other hand, the interest rate of long-term deposits increased by 2.5%. Hence, investing in bank deposits has not been an attractive choice for investors to cover the risk of decreasing their money value. There have almost been such conditions regarding the bank loans to different sectors of the economy (the data are presented in Table 1).

Table 1 The inflation rate, the interest rate of bank deposits and loans, exchange rates in (1979–2018)

There have been some flexibilities in the legislation about the interest rate of long-term deposits in 2007 and 2008. More specifically, in 2014, after decreasing limitations about IR, the new central bank team applied an economic reformation. They set a new monetary policy for the stability of the inflation rate. They adjusted the relationship between the interest rate of bank loans, short-, and long-term deposits with the inflation rate. As shown in Table 1, the data of 2015–2018 approve the results of this policy. After applying this policy, the proportion of inflation rate with the interest rate of bank loans, short-, and long-term deposits improved. In sum, as a result of the above discussion, the central bank and its monetary policy instrument of IR have mainly been passive against the inflation rate in most years.

In addition to the legislation of limitation in using IR after the revolution in 1979 and economic and political sanctions, the gap between official and unofficial foreign exchange rates (Rial against US dollar) has been the other reality in Iran’s economy since then. Regarding Table 1, there has been a single rate for domestic currency against the US dollar in 1974–1978. Nevertheless, after the revolution in 1979, forming the gap has gotten started and kept increasing until 2003. The central bank applied a new monetary policy in 2003, which was the unification of the exchange rate. Based on Table 1, the gap between official and unofficial rates decreased after applying this policy from 2003 to 2011. After 2011, the monetary policy of exchange rate unification did not continue due to the USA sanctions on oil and its derivatives exports of Iran (Tayebi and Sadeghi 2017).

Given fixed exchange rate and the role of the central bank in supporting the targeted exchange rate by supplying enough foreign currencies in the market to make a balance between demand and supply, due to severe reduction of the central bank’s foreign currencies reserves, the central bank could not keep supporting the targeted exchange rate through supplying foreign currency proportional with demand level. This issue again created the gap between official and unofficial rates. In other words, the monetary policy of exchange rate unification was defeated after passing 8 years. As presented in Table 1, the mentioned gap kept increasing from 2011 to 2018.

As a whole, after a change in the political and governance structures in 1979, given the new government's different political view in global geography, Iran has continuously been in tension with the influential global economies, the U.S., European Union, as well as the United Kingdom. On the other hand, a high dependence of foreign currency resources of the Central Bank on oil and its derivatives exports, and the low share of other products in the export basket, have always been one of the structural weaknesses of Iran's economy. In addition, the government’ budget also has a noticeably dependence on the receipts of oil exports. Hence, due to the political nature of the oil commodity along with its economic nature, and the fixed exchange rate that requires sufficient supply of foreign currencies to the market, the effects of political tensions spread to the foreign currency market through oil shocks. Consequently, the lack of sufficient supply of foreign currencies proportional with the demand level, and being covered an important part of the government’s budget deficit resulting from a decrease in oil export by a non-independent central bank and its printing money, cause a gap between foreign exchange rates.

One of the monetary policy instruments that could have influenced the exchange rate unification has been IR (due to its impact on the opportunity cost of holding money and the attractiveness of the domestic economy to absorb foreign investment). Nevertheless, as previously mentioned, the central bank is faced with limitations in using that because of the legislation. So, the gap between exchange rates and their high fluctuations has made an opportunity to gain profits from speculation in the FEM. This issue has turned the FEM into a substitute for the banking sector and the stock market in attracting liquidity. Absorbing liquidity in financial markets (stock market, bank deposits, and speculation in the FEM) might have different effects on an economy’s nominal and real sectors. In particular, being inadequate of firms’ financial resources and, at the same time, high incentives of speculative activities in the FEM have been one of the biggest problems in Iran’s economy. Hence, given that being influenced every three markets by monetary policy instrument of IR (it will be discussed later in Sect. 3), the role of the central bank and its monetary policy could be determinant on investors’ decision to invest in any of these markets.

Regarding the above discussion, both monetary policies of exchange rate unification and changing NIR proportional to inflation rate have faced limitations. One of them is the limitations in total foreign currencies reserves of the central bank and another one with “banking without free-interest rate” legislation. However, there have also been flexibilities in both of them. Because there have been times when the oil and its derivatives exports have been high, and thus, the central bank could keep applying the policy of exchange rate unification through supporting the targeted exchange rate by supplying enough foreign currency proportional with the demand level. On the other hand, they could take advantage of the legislation’s flexibility to adjust the relationship between NIR and the inflation rate. The importance of paying attention to both monetary policies is due to probable direct and indirect effects on nominal and real sectors of Iran’s economy. Since they might have direct effects on inflation and investment or indirect impacts on them through affecting the conditions of the stock market and bank deposits and loans (it will be discussed later in Sect. 3).

3 Background literature

We do pay attention to monetary policy effects on the nominal (inflation) and real sectors of the economy (investment and growth rate). In this respect, two monetary policies are considered. The first one involves affecting the FEM and the policy of exchange rate unification to lower the gap between official and unofficial exchange rates. The second one involves using monetary policy instrument of IR in order to influence the nominal and real sectors of the economy through the channels of the FIs (stock market and bank deposits) and speculation in the FEM, in other words, evaluating the direct and indirect impacts of IR on the economy. Given the policies mentioned above, it is essential to review the relationship between the FIs and the FEM with each other and with the nominal and real economic indicators. Since the monetary policy is supposed to affect the economy through these markets and its direct effects. Hence, to this aim, we review the related literature in the following four sub-titles.

3.1 The FIs and the nominal and real sectors of an economy

Levine (1999, 2005, 2000), and Greenbaum et al. (2019) state that the FIs have a positive impact on investment and economic growth through their roles in increasing transparency, reducing asymmetric information, facilitating transactions and trade, risk management, and lowering the costs of accessing to investment opportunities in order to attract and optimally allocate resources to productive economic activities. Some studies, such as Fufa and Kim (2018) and Seven and Yetkiner (2016), approved the positive effect of the banking sector and the stock market on economic growth. Schumpeter (1954) and McKinnon (1982) also assert that the FIs can be effective on growth rate due to their vital role in financing investment. On this basis, an essential part of the World Bank’s recommendations to the economies is to support structural reformations that the most important of those have been not repressing NIR and exchange rate and development of the stock market and banking sector (Balogun et al. 2016).

The firm’s financing in all economies is centered on the banking sector and stock market, any of which has a relatively large share in some economies than the other (Levine 2002). The financing system is market based in high-income countries (Demirguc-Kunt and Levine 1999) and bank based in developing ones (Moradi et al. 2016). There might be a competition between the FIs to attract liquidity. Hence, they try to absorb more liquidity through offering financial services and investment opportunities (Mattana and Panetti 2014). However, the FIs can complement each other because of the banking sector’s investment in the stock market and supply funds to the firms listed on the stock market (Adrian and Shin 2010).

On the other hand, economic conditions can also affect the FIs (Demirguc-Kunt and Levine 1999; Greenwood and Smith 1997; Sadeghi et al. 2021). Since in the economic boom, firms’ earnings increase, which has an expected positive impact on the stock market (Bahmani-Oskooee and Saha 2016). Accordingly, since IR is being affected by economic conditions, the incentive of investing in bank deposits is also affected (Boyd et al. 2001).

Inflation can have two different effects on the stock market. The positive effect is due to the growth of firms’ products price, and the negative effect is due to rising input prices and, thus, their cost effect (Al-haji et al. 2018; Chen et al. 1986). Another channel of inflation’s effectiveness is its potential impact on RIR, which can affect the attractiveness of bank deposits and, therefore, the costs of financing firms from bank deposits through changing the motivations to lend and borrow (Boyd et al. 2001). On the other hand, the stock market can also affect the inflation rate through the wealth effect channel. With a change in the stock market’s return, individuals’ expected income and wealth will also change. After that, household consumption, aggregate demand, and inflation will be affected (Simo-Kengne et al. 2015).

Rangan and Inglesi-Lotz (2012) and Antonakakis et al. (2017) confirm that inflation might affect the stock market and can be affected by the stock market. This bidirectional relation can be positive or negative, which is confirmed by Valcarcel (2012). Friedman (1977) states that rising inflation will harm investment due to growth of uncertainty and risk in the economy. Thus, the stock market will also be affected negatively (Apergis and Eleftheriou 2002). Tobin (1965) states that rising inflation positively affects the stock market because of devaluing cash value, savings, and thus injecting liquidity into the capital assets. Al-haji et al. (2018), based on Fisher’s (1930) study, discuss that after increasing inflation, investment in the stock market increases to cover the risk of depreciation of some assets. Some studies, such as the study of Boyd et al. (2001), have confirmed the negative effect of inflation on the banking sector and the stock market. Solarin et al. (2018) showed the negative effect of inflation on bank deposits, and on the contrary, Finger and Hesse (2009) found out that inflation had a positive effect on bank deposits. In the studies, like Bahmani-Oskooee and Saha (2016), inflation’s effect on the stock market has been negative in some countries and positive in some other ones. Antonakakis et al. (2017) found out that the impact of inflation on the stock market has been significant but different in different periods. The study of Thampanya et al. (2020) concluded that inflation affected the stock market positively.

3.2 The relationship of FEM with the nominal and real sectors of the economy

The studies of the World Bank have shown that the growth of exchange rate can increase bank deposits and, consequently, the growth of capital accumulation, investment, and economic growth. The best example is China where has benefited from this policy and achieved high economic growth. Some Asian countries, such as South Korea, Malaysia, and Thailand, did the same, and hence, their GDP and saving rate have shown high growth. On this basis, the net exports and, consequently, domestic savings will also grow after increasing the exchange rate, which causes the growth of competitiveness of exporting domestic goods in international markets and going up the import costs. As the saving rate grows, the needed domestic sources for financing the investment could be provided (Montiel and Serven 2008). Yeyati and Sturzenegger (2010) have also confirmed a rise in the exchange rate, and consequently, the increase of domestic savings to finance investments will lead to economic growth.

Concerning the effects of exchange rate on economic growth, the current views contrast with each other. Another view believes that the increase of exchange rate harms investment and economic growth due to the growth of the relative prices, domestic inflation, and more uncertainty in the economic environment (Montiel and Serven 2008; Dooley et al. 2004). There is a view that emphasizes the impacts of exchange rate on the economy depend on the structure of domestic economic firms. More specifically, the dependence of domestic firms on the measure of imported input against their exporting products might be a determinant factor (Bahmani-Oskooee and Saha 2016). As Comunale and Simola (2018) have approved, it relates to the relationship between exchange rate and inflation. The exchange rate pass-through on the inflation rate has been investigated by plenty of studies (Kurtovic et al. 2018). Ho and Odhiambo (2018) showed the negative effect of inflation on the exchange rate. In contrast, Delgado et al. (2018) reached a positive bidirectional relationship between inflation and exchange rates. On the other hand, the national currency value can also be affected by conditions of investment, economic growth, and inflation rate (Tayebi and Sadeghi 2017; Chiu and Sun 2016). In this regard, estimating the impacts of exchange rate changes on the inflation rate and then the monetary policy response to that has always been a challenge for central banks (Ghartey 2019).

3.3 The relationship between the FEM and the FIs

In the case of price instability and its high fluctuations in financial markets, the opportunity to profit from speculation due to high capital gains is provided, and thus, a substitute market is formed for the FIs in attracting liquidity. One of the financial markets that have the potential of high volatility and getting multi-rated due to the difference between official and unofficial rates is the FEM. Allen and Gale (1997) state that the difference between speculative activities and the FIs in attracting liquidity is related to their risk. Investors will take more risk when they expect a higher expected return. If they estimate more profit from the speculation than the FIs, they will choose the speculation. Dornbusch and Fisher (1980) and Bahmani-Oskooee and Saha (2016) express that a currency depreciation enhances the export-based firms’ income by reinforcing the competitiveness of their products in the international markets.

In contrast, the firms whose input is more dependent on importing might be affected negatively by a decrease in national currency value because of rising import costs. Therefore, given its impact on the profitability of export-based firms or relied on import of input, the FEM has the potential of different effects on the stock market. In this respect, Aggarwal (2003) found out that the effects of exchange rate fluctuations on stock price depend on their impacts on the firms’ products and input price. Franck and Young (1972) also confirmed that its impact depends on the structure of the firms. Exchange rate fluctuations also can affect bank deposits regarding their impact on the stock market, net exports, economic growth, and domestic savings. On the other side, given the potential effectiveness of the FIs on investment and economic growth that is a strong backup for the national currency, the FEM can also be mutually influenced by the conditions of the FIs. In this regard, Branson (1981) expresses that the exchange rate might be affected by capital assets price.

Some economic events and empirical studies have confirmed the existence of a negative correlation between financial markets. During the financial crisis of 2008–2009, the trust in the banking network had faded (Gregorioua et al. 2016), and the US stock market had also lost plenty of its value. The Federal Reserve led the investors’ liquidity to the stock market by taking advantage of expansionary monetary policy, bond buying, and lowering IR (Huang et al., 2016). Matana and Panetti (2014) have confirmed the negative correlation between bank deposits and the stock market. Solarin et al. (2018) reached a negative relationship between bank deposits and the FEM. The negative relation between the FEM and stock market has also been confirmed in several studies (Al-haji et al. 2018; Delgado et al. 2018; Huang et al., 2016; Assefa et al. 2017).

In contrast, some other studies have rejected the negative correlation between some of these markets and considered them as complement and reinforce each other due to the positive correlation. The stock market index in the study of Solarin et al. (2018) showed a positive relationship with bank deposits. Chen and Chiang (2016) and Ho and Odhiambo (2018) also reached the positive effect of the exchange rate on the stock market. The positive relation between banking credits and the stock market is also confirmed by the study of Ho and Odhiambo (2018).

Despite being confirmed of a significant bidirectional relation between the FEM and stock markets (Manasseh et al. 2019 and Thampanya et al. 2020), some studies have not shown a significant relationship with bank facilities (Mbutor, 2010). Chkili and Nguyen (2013) considered a non-linear relation for the stock market and the FEM. This study shows that the exchange rate has not significantly affected the stock market in both regimes of high and low fluctuations. In contrast, the stock market has shown a significant impact on the exchange rate in both regimes. The study of Samadi et al. (2021) also shows that there can be no significant relationship between the stock market and the FEM.

3.4 Monetary policy, the FIs, and the FEM

Central bank’s monetary decisions concerning changing IR can potentially impact stock market fluctuations, the FEM, bonds (Lyócsa et al. 2019), and cash value. Hence, the investors consider the IR changes on their decisions (Moya-Martínez et al. 2015). The financial crisis of 2008–2009, which slowed down the growth of the global economy, increased the attention to the potential of monetary policy and its IR instruments. IR is one of the determinants of stock price, and its relation with the stock market has considerable importance in financial economics (Moya-Martínez et al., 2015). Hashemzadeh and Taylor (1988) argue that a lower IR could positively affect the stock market through the growth of the current value of the future return. Furthermore, IR can affect economic growth by influencing the stock market (Balogun et al., 2016). In addition, IR is one of the influential factors in the absorption of bank deposits (Finger and Hesse 2009). By changing IR, the effects of monetary policy can be injected into the economy’s real and nominal sectors through the channel of affecting the FIs and the FEM. It is confirmed by Blinder (1998). Adrian and Shin (2010) also emphasize the transition of monetary policy effects to the economy’s real sectors through the channel of the FIs.

IR can be effective on bank deposits’ attractiveness and, consequently, the firms’ access listed on the stock market to bank loans for investing and, thus, their profitability outlook (El Wassal 2005; Yartey 2008). The effects of monetary policy on real sectors of an economy considerably depend on the status of the FIs (Terra and Arestis 2017; Beck et al. 2014). The changes of IR affect investors’ decisions to choose between risky assets and bank deposits. After rising IR, the investors might prefer bank deposits to risky assets. It increases the lending power of banks. Thus, the manufacturing sectors have more access to banking loans, leading to more investment (Beck et al. 2014). However, IR can also have a different and dual effect because it might increase the cost of financing the investment from bank loans, leading to a decrease in investment (Montiel and Serven 2008). Therefore, the performance and profitability perspective of the firms will be affected negatively by that. Some studies have confirmed the positive effect of IR on the growth of bank deposits (Mushtaq and Siddiqui 2017; Mashamba et al. 2014; Solarin et al. 2018; Ojeaga et al. 2013).

Nevertheless, the positive effect of raising IR on bank deposits in empirical studies that have mostly been related to Islamic countries has often been rejected. They found it out ineffective. (Hassan 2016; Mushtaq and Siddiqui 2017). Studies, such as Balogun et al. (2016), have shown the negative impact of IR liberalization on stock market development. Al-haji et al. (2018) and Huang et al. (2016) have also confirmed the negative effect of IR. In contrast, the study of Thampanya et al. (2020) found out that IR affects the stock market positively, and some others did not show a significant effect (Assefa et al. 2017). As a result, the changes of IR might affect the investors’ decision about investing in bank deposits or the stock market. For example, bank deposits will be less attractive than bank deposits if IR decreases because the RIR of bank deposits reduces, while the financing cost of the firms listed on the stock market decrease. Nevertheless, the impact of this substitution is not clear on real sectors of an economy. Does it depend on whether the stock market will be able to compensate for the reduction of firms’ access to financial resources of bank deposits or not? (Drechsler, Savov and Schnabl 2018; Lin 2020).

IR has enough potential to affect money demand and, therefore, the exchange rate due to its impact on the opportunity cost of holding money (Walsh 2010) and the attractiveness of the domestic economy to absorb foreign investment (Chen et al. 2016; Snowdon and Vane 2005). On the other hand, IR can affect the exchange rate through the channel of effectiveness on the FIs and, consequently, on investment and economic growth (El Wassal 2005; Yartey 2008), which are considered a strong backup for national currency value. Friedman states that if the return rate of different assets (money, stocks, bonds, and commodities) is not equal, the investors will tend to the assets with a higher return rate (Wright 2012). Given the possible effect of IR on money demand, exchange rate, and real return rate of bank deposits, the foreign currencies, and bank deposits can be added to the assets list considered by Friedman. However, some studies have not confirmed the effect of IR on exchange rates (Saraç and Karagöz 2016), and some others have shown a significant relationship between them (Taylor and Peel 2000).

Finally, given the existing four sub-titles, the monetary policy effects can be transmitted to the economy through the FIs and the FEM channel. As Blinder (1998), Allen and Gale (2004) and Adrian and Shin (2010) did confirm that. In this regard, Fernández-Amador et al. (2013) state that the intervention of central banks in the financial markets has been risen by applying the monetary policy to stabilize the markets and economic conditions after the financial crisis in 2007–2008.

4 Model specification and estimation method

This study investigates the effects of monetary policy on nominal and real sectors of Iran’s economy by channel of the relation between the stock market, bank deposits, and speculation in the FEM. Hence, the monetary policy instrument that can realize this link between the FIs, the FEM, and Monetary policy is IR. So in addition to the direct effects of IR, the indirect impacts of IR have been assessed by considering its effects on the economy through influencing the FIs and the FEM. We considered the regime changes due to high and low volatilities of dependent variables in Iran’s Economy as Hamilton (1989) considered regime switching model based on the abrupt changes. There has rarely been stability about these variables, and they have continually faced the transition between high and low volatility. While due to the stability of inflation rate in the developed and emerging economies, the previous studies have not paid enough attention to the probable relationship between the speculative activities in the FEM and the FIs and their competition over attracting liquidity and the potential of monetary policy to take advantage of that to influence the economy. The models of our study are presented below:

$${\text{INV}}_{{\text{t}}} = {\text{b}}_{{1}} + {\text{b}}_{{{11},{\text{ St}}}} {\text{INV}}_{{{\text{t}} - {1}}} + {\text{ b}}_{{{12},{\text{ St}}}} {\text{STO}}_{{\text{t}}} + {\text{b}}_{{{13},{\text{St}}}} {\text{DEP}}_{{\text{t}}} + {\text{b}}_{{{14},{\text{ St}}}} {\text{EX}}_{{\text{t}}} + {\text{b}}_{{{15}}} {\text{IR}}_{{\text{t}}} + {\text{b}}_{{{16}}} {\text{MED}}_{{\text{t}}} + {\text{b}}_{{{17}}} {\text{GOV}}_{{\text{t}}} ,$$
(1)
$${\text{CPI}}_{{\text{t}}} = {\text{b}}_{{2}} + {\text{b}}_{{{21},{\text{ St}}}} {\text{CPI}}_{{{\text{t}} - {1}}} + {\text{b}}_{{{22},{\text{ St}}}} {\text{STO}}_{{\text{t}}} + {\text{b}}_{{{23},{\text{ St}}}} {\text{DEP}}_{{\text{t}}} + {\text{b}}_{{{24},{\text{ St}}}} {\text{EX}}_{{\text{t}}} + {\text{b}}_{{{25}}} {\text{GDP}}_{{\text{t}}} + {\text{b}}_{{{26}}} {\text{M}}_{{\text{t}}} ,$$
(2)
$${\text{DEP}}_{{\text{t}}} = {\text{b}}_{{3}} + {\text{b}}_{{{31},{\text{ St}}}} {\text{DEP}}_{{{\text{t}} - {1}}} + {\text{b}}_{{{32},{\text{ St}}}} {\text{STO}}_{{\text{t}}} + {\text{b}}_{{{33},{\text{ St}}}} {\text{EX}}_{{\text{t}}} + {\text{b}}_{{{34},{\text{ St}}}} {\text{CPI}}_{{\text{t}}} + {\text{b}}_{{{35}}} {\text{IR}}_{{\text{t}}} + {\text{b}}_{{{36}}} {\text{GDP}}_{{\text{t}}} + {\text{b}}_{{{37}}} {\text{M}}_{{\text{t}}} ,$$
(3)
$${\text{STO}}_{{\text{t}}} = {\text{b}}_{{4}} + {\text{b}}_{{{41},{\text{ St}}}} {\text{STO}}_{{{\text{t}} - {1}}} + {\text{b}}_{{{42},{\text{ St}}}} {\text{DEP}}_{{\text{t}}} + {\text{b}}_{{{43},{\text{ St}}}} {\text{EX}}_{{\text{t}}} + {\text{b}}_{{{44},{\text{ St}}}} {\text{CPI}}_{{\text{t}}} + {\text{b}}_{{{45}}} {\text{IR}}_{{\text{t}}} + {\text{b}}_{{{46}}} {\text{GDP}}_{{\text{t}}} + {\text{b}}_{{{47}}} {\text{M}}_{{\text{t}}} ,$$
(4)
$${\text{EX}}_{{\text{t}}} = {\text{b}}_{{5}} + {\text{b}}_{{{51},{\text{ St}}}} {\text{EX}}_{{{\text{t}} - {1}}} + {\text{b}}_{{{52},{\text{ St}}}} {\text{DEP}}_{{\text{t}}} + {\text{b}}_{{{53},{\text{ St}}}} {\text{STO}}_{{\text{t}}} + {\text{b}}_{{{54},{\text{ St}}}} {\text{CPI}}_{{\text{t}}} + {\text{b}}_{{{55}}} {\text{IR}}_{{\text{t}}} + {\text{b}}_{{{56}}} {\text{GDP}}_{{\text{t}}} + {\text{b}}_{{{57}}} {\text{M}}_{{\text{t}}} .$$
(5)

The equation number (1) is the investment (INV) which includes the variables: stock market (STO), bank deposits (DEP), foreign exchange rate speculation (EX), real interest rate (IR), the imports value of input (MED), and government’s expenses (GOV). We survey the impacts of the FIs (DEP and STO), EX, and IR on INV. Plus, given the high level of GOV in Iran’s economy, we intend to determine whether GOV has had a complementary or substitutive impact on the private sector’s investment. Finally, we used MED due to the high dependence of domestic firms on input imports.

Equation number (2) is the consumer price index (CPI). The variables of STO, DEP, EX, IR, Gross Domestic Product (GDP), and coins and bills in people’s hands (M) have been used. We investigate the impacts of DEP, STO, EX, and IR on CPI, as we did that to equation INV. In addition to that, we considered M due to the high level of the coin and bills in people’s hands and oil exports (OIL) considering the high dependence of total reserves of foreign currencies on that. In order to define the equation CPI, we took some help from the studies of Dhakal et al. (1994) and Delgado et al. (2018).

The equation number (3) is bank deposits. We intend to find out what relation there will be between DEP, STO, and EX in different regimes of DEP. We will do the same for equations number (4) and (5), assigning STO and EX orderly. We evaluate these relations in different regimes of STO and EX in order for Eqs. (4) and (5). As Amisano and Fagan (2013), Bahloul et al. (2017) did consider two regimes for inflation and the stock market. Plus, Lee and Chen (2006) emphasized using Markov switching models for the exchange rates. As mentioned above, we did the same for INV and DEP in addition to EX, STO, and CPI.

For more details, we used the same variables of M, GDP, and CPI for Eqs. (3), (4), and (5). In the definition of Eq. (3), the study of Solarin et al. (2018) has been considered. We also noticed the studies of Assefa et al. (2017), Thampanya et al. (2020), Bahmani-Oskooee and Saha (2016), and Hashemzadeh and Taylor (1988) to define Eq. (4). To Eq. (5), we got some help from the studies of Mbutor (2010) and Kia (2013). Given the explanations mentioned above, in brief, investment (Eq. 1) and inflation rate or CPI (Eq. 2) are considered real and nominal sectors of Iran’s economy. We are supposed to survey the monetary policy effects on nominal and real economic indicators through influencing three markets of STO (Eq. 4), DEP (Eq. 3), and EX (Eq. 5).

Furthermore, a monetary policy instrument is needed to have enough potential to affect the liquidity flow between DEP, STO, and EX, which can influence the nominal and real sectors of the economy (CPI and INV) through this channel. To this aim, the real interest rate (IR) is used. In this respect, we put IR in every three equations of STO, DEP, and EX. In this way, we can compare the impacts of monetary policy on these three markets. On the other hand, we put every three markets of STO, DEP, and EX in equation INV and CPI. Now, we will have a comparative analysis concerning the results of five estimations. Hence, we will evaluate the effects of monetary policy on inflation and investment through the channel of affecting the mentioned three markets. Necessary to say that the impacts of IR are not considered dependent on the regime due to the repression of NIR and being passive of the real interest rate against the inflation rate.

All mentioned variables have been used in their growth forms for the period 1988–2018. Finally, St is assumed exogenous and represents the regime and the variables affected by the regime in Eqs. 15. For EX, we used the gap between official and unofficial Iran’s domestic currency (Rial) against the U.S. dollar published by Iran’s Central Bank. This gap can boost the motivations of gaining profits from speculation in the FEM. For DEP, we took into account the averege of short-term and long-term bank deposits released by Iran’s Central Bank. For STO, we applied the value of stocks traded on the stock market published by Iran’s Central Bank. To INV, the gross fixed capital formation published by Iran’s Central Bank has been used. For consumer price index, gross domestic product, and government’s expenses, we used the information of the World Bank. For IR and M, the real interest rate of bank deposits, and coins and bills in people’s hands, Iran’s Central Bank’s data have been applied.

The time series faces sudden changes called the regime transition in the econometric literature (Hamilton 1989). The main feature of regime-dependent models is that the number of regimes is finite, and the transition between them can be slow or very fast (Franke 2012). It typically assumes the regime changes are exogenous concerning all realizations of the regression disturbance (Hamilton 1989). Markov switching models allow the influence of explanatory variables to be regime depended. These models include different kinds. Given which part of the model is dependent on the regime, it can be MSM which the mean is dependent on the regime, MSH that the variance is dependent, MSA (dependence of autoregressive coefficients), MSH (dependence of constant term), and or a combination of these four kinds. Given the annual time series and the number of the observation which is 30, we considered at most four lags. The number of regimes is set based on the fluctuations of every five dependent variables in Iran’s economy. We had faced high or low volatility about these five variables, and there has rarely been stability. That was why we chose two regimes as the most empirical studies did the same.

5 Empirical results

After confirming all variables’ stationery by augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF) test, the necessity of using non-linear evaluation is examined by the likelihood ratio (LR) test. Then, one of Markov’s models has been selected regarding the models’ explanatory (Log-Likelihood), Schwartz criterion (number of observations less than one hundred), and the significance of the coefficients, especially regimes’ coefficients. The results of the mentioned cases are shown in Table 2.

Table 2 The number of regimes and lags and LR test

Based on Table 2, after being approved the non-linear relations for every five equations, setting lags, regimes number, and selecting one of Markov switching models, the estimation results of five equations are presented in separated Tables 3, 4, 5, 6, 7.

Table 3 The estimation results of equation INV
Table 4 The estimation results of equation CPI

According to Table 3, regime (0) indicates a higher mean, as the boom and regime (1) are set as the recession. In both regimes, the FIs of the stock market and bank deposits have positively affected investment. This positive effect has been severe in the recession. In contrast, speculation in the FEM has shown a negative impact on investment in both regimes. This negative effect has been more remarkable in the recession. These results show that speculation in the FEM can negatively affect investment if high capital gains originated from exchange rates differences to attract more liquidity than the FIs. This negative effect might be because of increasing the costs through boosting the exchange rate and thus getting expensive the imports of input due to considerable dependence of domestic firms to imported input. One more reason can be related to financing through the FIs. Because after leading more liquidity to speculation in the FEM than the FIs, the firms’ access to resources will probably decline.

Previous period investment has also shown a positive impact. The government’s expenses affected investment negatively. This result shows that it has not had a complementary effect on the private sector’s investment. The military expenses (as a signal for security) have had a positive effect. Imports of intermediate goods and input has positively affected investment, probably because of the high dependence of manufacturing sectors on imported input. IR has had a positive effect on investment. A probable explanation is that being negative of RIR due to the inflationary environment and NIR repression reduced the firms’ financing cost from bank loans over time. The transition matrix shows that the persistence probability of the boom regime is relatively higher than the recession—an average of 2.41 years for the boom and 1.71 for the recession. In addition, the probability of the transition from a recession to a boom was higher than the reverse (from a boom to a recession).

Based on Table 4, regime (0) shows very high CPI due to a more effective mean, and regime (1) high CPI. The FIs of bank deposits and the stock market have negatively affected CPI that has been more remarkable in regime (0). This negative effect has formed by attracting more liquidity by the FIs and, thus, not leading liquidity to the markets that potentially provoke false demands. In contrast, speculation in the FEM has shown a positive effect on CPI in regime (0), while its effect has been insignificant in regime (1). A probable explanation is that the speculative activities could not create enough false demand to move price levels up when the economy was in regime (1). But, being affected the general price level by speculation in the FEM through creating high false demand has been more remarkable when we faced a very high inflationary environment in regime (0).

GDP and oil exports have had a negative effect. Coin and bills in people’s hands showed a positive impact. Expected inflation (the lag of the previous period) has shown a positive effect in regime (0) and a negitive impact in regime (1). The transition matrix indicates that the probability of persistency of both regimes is high and close to each other, and on the other hand, the persistency of regime (0) is relatively higher than regime (1). In addition, the transition probability of a high CPI to a very high CPI regime is higher than the reverse. Plus, the probability of transition from regime (0) to regime (1) or vice versa is low. This result indicates the average years of regimes persistency is high when the economy enters one of these regimes—an average of 3 years for the regime (0) and 3 years for the regime (1).

Based on Table 5, regime (0) suggests a bull market due to higher mean and regime (1) bear market. Bank deposits have had a negative relation with the stock market. Its negative effect has been more remarkable in regime (0). This relation indicates competition between two FIs to attract liquidity and lack a complementary effect on each other.

The high difference between the official and unofficial exchange rates positively affected the stock market in bull regime. In contrast, its effect has been negative in the bear market. In a bull market, the firms’ profitability outlook has increased due to the growth of their exporting products after increasing the exchange rate by reinforcing their products’ competitiveness in the international market. While in the bear market, with an increase of exchange rate and growth of the input import cost, the negative share of its production cost has overcome its positive effect on the sale of export products, and hence, it affected the stock market negatively.

CPI has shown a positive impact due to the rising price of products in both regimes. Expectations (the stock market lags) have positively affected stock market in bull regime and negitively impacted it in bear regime. The coin and bills in people’s hands and also GDP affected the stock market positively. The relation of IR with the stock market has been negative due to the increase of financing costs from bank loans, but this relation has been insignificant due to the repression of NIR. The transition matrix indicates that the persistency probability of both regimes is high, which concerning the bull market, this probability has been higher. In addition, the transition probability from a bull market to a bear market is remarkably lower than the reverse. The point is that the probability of regime changing or transition between two regimes is low. When the stock market enters one of these regimes, the number of years which remain in that is high, with an average of 4.25 years for the bull regime and 3.67 for the bear regime.

According to Table 6, regime (0) shows high deposits due to the more effective mean, and regime (1) indicates the low deposits. In both regimes, the stock market has had a negative relation with bank deposits. This negative relation has been more remarkable in regime (0). This result is the same as the result of STO estimation in Table 5, which showed bank deposits and the stock market had no complementary impact on each other, but there has been competition between them to attract more liquidity.

Table 5 The estimation results of equation STO

The difference between official and unofficial exchange rates has affected bank deposits positively in regime (0), and in contrast, its effect has been negative in regime (1). Therefore, given estimation results in Tables 5 and 6, in the periods that the FIs of bank deposits and the stock market have been in a recession, the speculation in the FEM might have been a solid competitor for them in attracting liquidity. Nevertheless, in the boom regimes of the FIs, this difference of exchange rates has reinforced them or has had a complementary effect on them. This result shows how much the state of the FIs can be critical in Iran’s economy in the direction in which the liquidity will be led. CPI has shown an adverse effect in regime (0) and a positive impact in regime (1). A probable explanation is that due to repression of NIR and facing high inflation in regime (0) originated from the great measure of M2, CPI has harmed deposits bank because of a lower RIR. There are the same explanations for its positive effect when we are not in a high inflationary environment because of being in regime (0) and thus facing the lower measure of M2 due to higher RIR.

Expectations (the lags of bank deposits) have had a positive effect in the regime (0) and a negative impact in the regime (1). In the following, the coin and bills in people’s hands and GDP have shown a positive effect. The impact of IR on bank deposits has been negative due to the negative RIR originated from high inflation and NIR repression in most years of the considered period. The transition matrix indicates that the persistency probability of both regimes has been high which we had a significantly higher probability for the regime (0) than regime (1)—an average of 7.67 years for high deposits and 3 for low deposits. In addition, the transition probability from high to low deposits has been very low compared to the reverse.

The last estimation is about the speculation in the FEM or the difference between foreign exchange rates. According to Table 7, regime (0) indicates high speculation in the FEM (high difference between official and unofficial rates) concerning the higher mean, and regime (1) is set as low speculation.

Table 6 The estimation results of equation DEP
Table 7 The estimation results of equation EX

The both FIs of the stock market and bank deposits have had a negative effect on the difference of exchange rates. This negative effect has been more remarkable in regime (0) for bank deposits and regime (1) for the stock market. This result shows that there has been competition for attracting liquidity between bank deposits and the stock market with speculation in the FEM. The negative impact of the FIs on foreign exchange rate speculation might have been due to the absorption of liquidity and, therefore, the reduction of injecting liquidity into the FEM for gaining profits from speculating. Another probable reason is that considering the positive effect of bank deposits and the stock market on investment in Table 3; these two FIs might have caused reducing the gap between exchange rates through the growth of investment and, therefore, reinforcing national currency value.

Expectations about the difference between exchange rates (the lags of EX) have had a positive impact in the regime (0) and a negative effect in the regime (1). Furthermore, the coin and bills in people’s hands and CPI have shown a positive effect. In contrast, investment affected the exchange rates difference negatively. Finally, the impact of IR has been positive. A possible explanation is that due to being negative of RIR originated from high inflation and repression of NIR in the most years of the considered period, the attractiveness of attracting foreign investment declined, and the incentive of taking bank loans went up. These two consequences of negative IR caused the weakening of national currency value, which lowered demand for money. Hence, the effect of IR on exchange rates difference has expectedly been positive.

The transition matrix shows that the persistency probability of high speculation regime (high exchange rates difference, regime (0)) is very high and, in contrast, is very low for the regime (1)—an average of 3.67 years for the regime (0) and 1.2 years for the regime (1). In addition, while the probability of a transition from the regime (0) to regime (1) has been very low, the reverse has been very high. This result confirms that the conditions for gaining profits from speculation in the FEM have been provided during the under-review period. Hence, the destructive effects of the exchange rates gap on general price level fluctuations, and investment will most likely be lasting in Iran’s economy.

6 Discussion

We are supposed to discuss how the monetary policy affects Iran’s economy’s nominal and real sectors through the FIs and the FEM channel. For this purpose, we have a comparative analysis about the obtained results of five estimations. First, bank deposits and the stock market have had a significant negative impact on CPI and positive on investment. This positive impact on investment and negative on inflation has existed in both regimes, whether the economy has been faced with high or very high inflation and recession or boom concerning investment. These results show the capacity and importance of the FIs in affecting the nominal and real sectors of the economy suitably. At the same time, the difference between official and unofficial exchange rates has had a significant positive impact on CPI and negative on investment in both regimes of CPI and investment. As discussed in Sect. 2, monetary policy in Iran’s economy has not had the acceptable impacts on the FEM after a revolution in 1979. The fixed exchange rate and not supporting the targeted exchange rate by the central bank caused the gap between exchange rates and the motivations of speculative activities in the FEM to gain short-term profits. The high demand level for foreign currency and leading more and more liquidity toward the FEM led to the growth of inflation rate and reduction of investment. The estimation results also confirmed our discussion in Sect. 2 concerning the destructive effects of not applying the policy of exchange rate unification on the economy. Hence, there is the necessity of applying this policy. Thus, in sum, despite Fernández-Amador et al. (2013), who believed the central bank intervention and their monetary policies have mainly been toward stabilizing the financial market and economic conditions after financial crises, the performance of Iran’s Central Bank and its monetary policy has not shown such a reality in the FEM. Thus, because of negative RIR, not affecting the stock market positively, and the existence of a gap between exchange rates, the liquidity has been attracted to speculative activities in the FEM instead of supporting productive economic activities through the FIs.

Some studies, such as Levine (1999), Beck and Levine (2004), and Ibrahim and Shah (2012), reached the same result about the positive effect of the FIs on investment and growth rate. Atella et al. (2003) obtained the negative effect of foreign exchange rates on investment (the difference of our study has been considering the difference between official and unofficial exchange rates). Antwi et al. (2020) concluded that the foreign exchange rate had a positive impact on inflation, as so did we. On the contrary, Antonakakis et al. (2017) concluded about the negative correlation between the stock market and inflation.

Second, the result showed that stock market and bank deposits had been a substitute to each other and not a complement regardless of being in bear or bull stock market and high or low deposits. Therefore, the central bank can choose one of them as the targeted market to attract more liquidity based on its monetary policy aims as Dey (2007) reached the same result about substituting the banking sector and stock market. Nevertheless, Arize et al. (2018) showed that the banking and stock markets complement each other. On the other hand, there has been a substitutive relation between the stock market and bank deposits with speculation in the FEM when they have been in the recession. Demir (2013) had the same result about the negative relation between the stock market and the fluctuations of the exchange rate.

Third, IR has also shown a significant adverse effect on bank deposits, positive on speculation in the FEM, and an insignificant impact on the stock market as Chen (2009) and Toraman and Başarir (2014) got the same result the insignificant effect of IR on the stock market. IR has shown an adverse effect in some countries and a positive impact in some more economies on bank deposits based on the study of Larionova and Varlamova (2014). The negative impact of IR on bank deposits has confirmed our discussion in Sect. 2. We discussed that the inflation rate had been more than the nominal interest rate of short- and long-term bank deposits from beginning 1979 to the end (except for 2015–2018) due to Islamic rules’ sensitivities to IR and, therefore, limitations of using IR by the central bank in the new political regime.

As a result, the real interest rate of this kind of deposit has been negative. As we discussed in Sect. 2 and the estimation results confirmed, investing in bank deposits has not been an attractive choice for investors to cover the risk of decreasing their money value. This issue got started from the presidency of BanisadrFootnote 2 as the first president in the new political regime and kept continuing in the next presidency of KhameneiFootnote 3 and Rafsanjani.Footnote 4 As a turning point, the profound consequences of this policy were revealed in the second term of Rafsanjani’s presidency. When inflation rate reached 49%, while NIR of short- and long-term were 8 and 14%, after that, in the period of Khatami’s presidency,Footnote 5 the proportion between inflation rate and NIR of bank deposits (especially long-term deposits) improved and continued till the middle of second Ahmadinejad’s presidencyFootnote 6 in 2012. The mentioned improvement could not continue in 2013–2014. However, we experienced the best policy in the first term of Rouhani’s presidencyFootnote 7 so that the NIR of deposits was more than the inflation rate in 2015–2018.

Plus, as we stated above, IR has positively impacted the gap between official and unofficial exchange rates. At the same time, there was an expectation about its negative effect based on related economic theories (as we had in Sect. 3, because of its impact on the opportunity cost of holding money and the attractiveness of the domestic economy to absorb foreign investment). Saraç and Karagöz (2016) also obtained the same result about not finding any decreasing effect of IR on exchange rate despite the claim of Turkey’s central bank based on controlling exchange rate by using IR. On this basis, Iran’s Central Bank and its monetary policy have not affected the gap between exchange rates suitably due to the limitations of applying the policy of exchange rate unification and using IR, as we already discussed in Sect. 2. More details, this gap got started from the presidency of Banisadr as the first president and kept increasing in the presidency of Khamenei, Rafsanjani, and Khatami till 2002. The policy of exchange rate unification was applied in the second term of Khatami’s presidency in 2003 and continued until the middle of Ahmadinejad’s presidency in 2011. The effects of this new policy were clear on lowering the gap between official and unofficial exchange rates in 2003–2011. Nevertheless, After 2011, in the last two years of second Ahmadinejad’s presidency and the start of the presidency of Rouhani to 2018, the monetary policy of exchange rate unification did not continue because of USA sanctions on oil and its derivatives exports.

On the other hand, given the second discussion based on the existence of substitutive relation between the FIs and the EFM and the different effects of the FIs and the EFM on nominal and real sectors of Iran’s economy and finally the third discussion relied on the potential effects of IR on the FIs and the FEM, we conclude: in the event of not repressing of NIR, the central bank and its monetary policy can affect the nominal and real sectors of Iran’s economy through the channel of the FIs and the FEM. As the studies of Terra and Arestis (2017) and Beck et al. (2014) did reach the same respecting the effectiveness of the monetary policy on the real sector of an economy through the channel of the FIs. Toraman and Başarir (2014) also concluded that central banks could affect the nominal (inflation) and real (employment) sectors of an economy through using IR in order to influence the stock market. Nevertheless, these studies did not consider other financial markets, like the FEM, due to the relative stability of the inflation rate or the low fluctuation of the general price level and the existence of a single foreign exchange rate. Therefore, as we discussed in Sect. 2, the legislation in 1984 and its limitations about using interest rates have taken an essential part of the central bank’s power to influence economic conditions through the FIs and the FEM.

7 Conclusion and policy implications

This study examines the effects of monetary policy on nominal (CPI) and real (investment) sectors of Iran’s economy through the channel of the relation between the stock market, bank deposits, and speculation in the FEM by applying Markov switching models for time 1988–2018. In this period, Iran’s economy faced the limitations of using IR by the central bank and banking sector and applying the policy of exchange rate unification. So, our concentration has been on monetary policies of exchange rate unification and using IR to transmit the impacts of monetary policy to the nominal and real sectors of the economy through the FIs and the FEM.

The results show that the nominal and real economic sectors are highly affected by the FIs and speculation in the FEM. Bank deposits and the stock market have negatively affected CPI in both regimes of high and very high CPI. In contrast, speculation in the FEM has indicated a positive impact on it in both regimes of CPI. Bank deposits and the stock market have had a positive effect on investment in both recession and boom regimes of investment. Nevertheless, speculation in the FEM affected it negatively in both regimes of investment. In other words, the impacts of the FIs on the nominal and real sectors of Iran’s economy have been different from the effects of speculation in the FEM. The main reason for the negative effect of foreign exchange rates on investment has been the gap between the exchange rates due to not applying the policy of exchange rate unification. On the other hand, the IR has shown a negative impact on bank deposits due to being negative of RIR in most years, and its effect on speculation in the FEM has been positive. The relation between IR and the stock market has been insignificant. However, we expected that IR would significantly influence the stock market, positively affect bank deposits, and negatively impact the gap between official and unofficial exchanges rate. These results show the destructive effects of the legislation and its limitations concerning using IR by central banks and the banking sector.

Given the obtained results, considering the substitutive relations between the FIs and speculation in the FEM and being affected of the nominal and real sectors of the economy by these relations and plus the different effects of IR on the FIs and the FEM, the policy makers and central bank must follow some important policies. First, they should make enough attraction in the stock market and bank deposits to absorb more liquidity to finance investment and productive economic activities adequately. In this way, the liquidity will not be attracted in markets where cause creating price fluctuation. The high price fluctuation forms a condition to speculative activities for gaining short-term profits. In other words, it makes the speculative activities in these markets get more attractive than investing in the FIs for financing the productive activities.

As we did see, the monetary policy had enough potential to realize the cases mentioned above. In this regard, monetary policy should be concentrated on applying the exchange rate unification to lower the gap between official and unofficial rates since this gap has had destructive effects on investment, growth rate, and inflation. A single foreign exchange rate reduces uncertainties regarding the firms’ performance and profitability outlook by having a reliable estimation about their import costs of input, the measure of export revenues, and the situation of the domestic economy. Second, regarding the direct and indirect effects of monetary policy instrument of interest rate on the real and nominal sectors of Iran’s economy through the channels of the FIs and the FEM, the legislation and the repression of NIR has taken a lot of opportunities from the central bank to adjust the relationship between the financial markets and leading liquidity between them in order to reach its monetary policy aims. Hence, it is essential to be reconsidered about the legislation or making other needed flexibilities to lift more limitations concerning using interest rates by central banks and the banking sector to support the productive activities and lower the motives of speculative activities. Because in this event, instead of being passive against the growth of inflation rate, the central bank will be able to change NIR proportional with the inflation rate for influencing the FIs and the FEM to transmit the monetary policy effects to the economy.

Availability of data and materials

The datasets used and/or analyzed during the current study are available from the corresponding author on reasonable request.

Notes

  1. There is a very high sensitivity to interest rate in Islamic rules. More specifically, the lenders cannot make their loans conditional on receiving a certain percentage of the principle of money. The interest rate, the same certain percentage added to the loan principle, is referred to as usury in Islamic rules. Although with the rise of the share of the banking sector in Islamic economies by the channel of bank deposits and loans, the level of this sensitivity has considerably decreased over time, there are still much restrictions for Iran’s Central Bank to take advantage of interest rate potential due to the legislation in 1984 resulting from Islamic rules.

  2. 1980–1981: The term of Banisadr’s presidency which lasted about two years.

  3. 1981–1989: The terms of Khamenei’s presidency.

  4. 1989–1997: The terms of Rafsanjani’s presidency.

  5. 1997–2005: The terms of Khatami’s presidency.

  6. 2005–2013: The terms of Ahmadinejad’s presidency.

  7. 2013–2018: The first term of Rouhani’s presidency.

Abbreviations

NIR:

Nominal interest rate

RIR:

Real interest rate

IR:

Interest rate

FIs:

Financial intermediaries

FEM:

Foreign Exchange Market

References

  • Adrian T, Shin HS (2010) Financial intermediaries and monetary economics. In: Handbook of monetary economics, 3, pp 601–650

  • Aggarwal R (2003) Exchange rates and stock prices: a study of the US capital markets under floating exchange rates. 7–12.

  • Al-hajj E, Al-Mulali U, Solarin A (2018) Oil price shocks and stock returns nexus for Malaysia: fresh evidence from nonlinear ARDL test. Energy Rep 4:624–637

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Allen F, Gale D (1997) Financial markets, intermediaries and intertemporal smoothing. J Polit Econ 105:523–546

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Allen F, Gale D (2004) Financial intermediaries and markets. Econometrica 72(4):1023–1061

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Amisano G, Fagan G (2013) Money growth and inflation: a regime switching approach. J Int Money Financ 33:118–145

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Antonakakis N, Gupta R, Tiwari AK (2017) Has the correlation of inflation and stock prices changed in the United States over the last two centuries? Res Int Bus Financ 42:1–8

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Antwi S, Issah M, Patience A, Antwi S (2020) The effect of macroeconomic variables on exchange rate: evidence from Ghana. Cogent Econ Finance 8(1):1821483

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Apergis N, Eleftheriou S (2002) Interest rates, inflation, and stock prices: the case of the Athens Stock Exchange. J Policy Model 24(3):231–236

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arize A, Kalu EU, Nkwor NN (2018) Banks versus markets: do they compete, complement or co-evolve in the Nigerian financial system? An ARDL approach. Res Int Bus Financ 45:427–434

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Assefa T, Esqueda A, Mollick V (2017) Stock returns and interest rates around the world: a panel data approach. J Econ Bus 89:20–35

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Atella V, Atzeni GE, Belvisi PL (2003) Investment and exchange rate uncertainty. J Policy Model 25(8):811–824

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bahloul S, Mroua M, Naifar N (2017) The impact of macroeconomic and conventional stock market variables on Islamic index returns under regime switching. Borsa Istanbul Rev 17(1):62–74

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bahmani-Oskooee M, Saha S (2016) Do exchange rate changes have symmetric or asymmetric effects on stock prices? Glob Financ J 31:57–72

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Balogun W, Dahalan J, Hassan S (2016) Long run impacts of interest rate liberalization on stock market development. Proc Soc Behav Sci 219:126–133

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beck T, Levine R (2004) Stock markets, banks, and growth: panel evidence. J Bank Finance 28(3):423–442

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beck T, Colciago A, Pfajfar D (2014) The role of financial intermediaries in monetary policy transmission. J Econ Dyn Control 43:1–11

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blinder A (1998) Central banking in theory and practice. MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Boyd JH, Levine R, Smith BD (2001) The impact of inflation on financial sector performance. J Monet Econ 47(2):221–248

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Branson WH (1981) Macroeconomic determinants of real exchange rates (No. w0801). National Bureau of Economic Research.

  • Chen X, Chiang TC (2016) Stock returns and economic forces—an empirical investigation of Chinese markets. Glob Financ J 30:45–65

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen PF, Lee C, Lee CC, Huang JX (2016) A dynamic analysis of exchange rate exposure: the impact of China’s Renminbi. World Econ 39(1):132–157

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen NF, Roll R, Ross SA (1986) Economic Forces and the Stock Market. J Bus 59(3):383. https://doi.org/10.1086/296344

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen SS (2009) Predicting the bear stock market: Macroeconomic variables as leading indicators. Journal of Banking & Finance 33(2):211–223

  • Chiu YB, Sun CHD (2016) The role of savings rate in exchange rate and trade imbalance nexus: cross-countries evidence. Econ Model 52:1017–1025

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chkili DW, Nguyen K (2013) Exchange rate movements and stock market returns in a regime-switching environment: evidence for BRICS countries. Res Int Bus Financ 31:46–56

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Comunale M, Simola H (2018) The pass-through to consumer prices in CIS economies: the role of exchange rates, commodities and other common factors. Res Int Bus Financ 44:186–217

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Delgado NB, Delgado EB, Saucedo E (2018) The relationship between oil prices, the stock market and the exchange rate: evidence from Mexico. N Am J Econ Finance 45:266–275

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Demir F (2013) Growth under exchange rate volatility: does access to foreign or domestic equity markets matter? J Dev Econ 100(1):74–88

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Demirguc-Kunt A, Levine R (1999) Bank-based and market-based financial systems cross-country comparisons. Policy Research Working Paper Series 2143, the World Bank.

  • Dey MK (2007) Are banks and stock markets complements or substitutes? Morgan State University, Baltimore

    Google Scholar 

  • Dhakal D, Kandil M, Sharma SC, Trescott PB (1994) Determinants of the inflation rate in the United States: a VAR investigation. Q Rev Econ Finance 34(1):95–112

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dooley MP, Folkerts-Landau D, Garber P (2004) The revived Bretton woods system. Int J Financ Econ 9(4):307–313

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dornbusch R, Fischer S (1980) Exchange rates and the current account. Am Econ Rev 70(5):960–971

    Google Scholar 

  • Drechsler I, Savov A, Schnabl P (2018) Banking on deposits: Maturity transformation without interest rate risk (No. w24582). National Bureau of Economic Research.

  • El Wassal KA (2005) Understanding the growth in emerging stocks market. J Emerg Market Finance 4:227–261

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fernández-Amador O, Gächter M, Larch M, Peter G (2013) Does monetary policy determine stock market liquidity? New evidence from the euro zone. J Empir Finance 21:54–68

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Finger MH, Hesse MH (2009) Lebanon-determinants of commercial bank deposits in a regional financial center. International Monetary Fund

  • Fisher I (1930) Theory of interest: as determined by impatience to spend income and opportunity to invest it. Augustusm Kelly Publishers, Clifton.

  • Franck P, Young A (1972) Stock price reaction of multinational firms to exchange realignments. Finance Manage 1:66–73

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Franke J (2012) Markov switching time series models. In: Handbook of statistics, vol. 30, Elsevier, Amsterdam. pp. 99–122

  • Friedman M (1977) Nobel lecture: inflation and unemployment. J Polit Econ 85(3):451–472

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fufa T, Kim J (2018) Stock markets, banks, and economic growth: evidence from more homogeneous panels. Res Int Bus Finance 44:504–517

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ghartey EE (2019) Asymmetries in exchange rate pass-through and monetary policy principle: some Caribbean empirical evidence. N Am J Econ Finance 47:325–335

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greenbaum SI, Thakor AV, Boot A (2019) Contemporary financial intermediation. Academic Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Greenwood J, Smith BD (1997) Financial markets in development, and the development of financial markets. J Econ Dyn Control 21(1):145–181

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gregoriou A, Gupta J, Healy J (2016) Does Islamic banking increase the liquidity of stocks? An application to the Kingdom of Bahrain. J Int Finan Markets Inst Money 42:132–138

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hamilton JD (1989) A new approach to the economic analysis of nonstationary time series and the business cycle. Econometrica J Econ Soc. https://doi.org/10.2307/1912559

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hashemzadeh N, Taylor P (1988) Stock prices, money supply, and interest rates: the question of causality. Appl Econ 20(12):1603–1611

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hassan OM (2016) Effect of interest rate on commercial bank deposits in Nigeria (2000–2013). In Proceeding of the First American Academic Research Conference on Global Business, Economics, Finance and Social Sciences (AAR16 New York Conference)

  • Ho SY, Odhiambo NM (2018) Analyzing the macroeconomic drivers of stock market development in the Philippines. Cogent Econ Finance 6(1):1451265

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huang W, Mollick AV, Nguyen KH (2016) US stock markets and the role of real interest rates. Q Rev Econ Finance 59:231–242

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ibrahim MH, Shah ME (2012) Bank lending, macroeconomic conditions and financial uncertainty: evidence from Malaysia. Review of Development Finance 2(3-4): 156–164.

  • Kia A (2013) Determinants of the real exchange rate in a small open economy: evidence from Canada. J Int Financ Markets Inst Money 23:163–178

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kurtović S, Siljković B, Denić N, Petković D, Mladenović SS, Mladenović I, Milovancevic M (2018) Exchange rate pass-through and Southeast European economies. Phys A 503:400–409

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Larionova N, Varlamova J (2014) Correlation analysis of macroeconomic and banking system indicators. Proc Econ Finance 14:359–366

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee HY, Chen SL (2006) Why use Markov-switching models in exchange rate prediction? Econ Model 23(4):662–668

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levine R (1999) Law, finance, and economic growth. J Financ Intermed 8(1–2):8–35

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levine R (2002) Bank-based or market-based financial systems: which is better? J Financ Intermed 11(4):398–428

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levine R (2005) Finance and growth: theory and evidence. Handb Econ Growth 1:865–934

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levine R, Loayza N, Beck T (2000) Financial intermediation and growth: causality and causes. J Monet Econ 46(1):31–77

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lin L (2020) Bank Deposits and the Stock Market. The Review of Financial Studies 33(6):2622–2658. https://doi.org/10.1093/rfs/hhz078

  • Lyócsa Š, Molnár P, Plíhal T (2019) Central bank announcements and realized volatility of stock markets in G7 countries. J Int Finan Markets Inst Money 58:117–135

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Manasseh CO, Chukwu O, Abada FC, Ogbuabor JE, Onyeka KA, Okoro OE (2019) Interactions between stock prices and exchange rates: an application of multivariate VAR-GARCH model. Cogent Econ Finance 7(1):1681573

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mashamba T, Magweva R, Gumbo L C (2014) Analysing the relationship between Banks’ Deposit Interest Rate and Deposit Mobilisation: Empirical evidence from Zimbabwean Commercial Banks (1980–2006)

  • Mattana E, Panetti E (2014) Bank liquidity, stock market participation, and economic growth. J Bank Finance 48:292–306

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mbutor OM (2010) Exchange rate volatility, stock price fluctuations and the lending behaviour of banks in Nigeria. J Econ Int Finance 2(11):251–260

    Google Scholar 

  • Mckinnon R (1982) Money and capital in economic development brookings, institution, Washington, DC 1973. Vozes Ed., Rio de Janeiro

  • Montiel PJ, Servén L (2008) Real exchange rates, saving and growth: Is there a link. World Bank Policy research working paper: (4636)

  • Moradi ZS, Mirzaeenejad M, Geraeenejad G (2016) Effect of bank-based or market-based financial systems on income distribution in selected countries. Proc Econ Finance 36:510–521

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moya-Martínez P, Ferrer-Lapena R, Escribano-Sotos F (2015) Interest rate changes and stock returns in Spain: a wavelet analysis. BRQ Bus Res Q 18(2):95–110

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mushtaq S, Siddiqui A (2017) Effect of interest rate on bank deposits: evidences from Islamic and non-Islamic economies. Future Bus J 3(1):1–8

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • -Ojeaga P, Ojeaga D, Odejimi DO (2013) The impact of interest rate on bank deposits evidence from the Nigerian banking sector

  • Rangan G, Inglesi-Lotz R (2012) Macro shocks and real US stock prices with special focus on the “Great Recession”

  • Sadeghi A, Marzban H, Samadi AH, Azarbaiejani K (2021) The relationship among stock market, bank deposits and foreign exchange speculation: An emphasis on the role of interest rate in Iran’s economy. Iranian Journal of Economic Research 87(26): 41–76.

  • Samadi AH, Owjimehr S, Nezhad Halafi Z (2021) The cross-impact between financial markets, COVID-19 pandemic, and economic sanctions: the case of Iran. J Policy Model 43(1):34–55

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Saraç TB, Karagöz K (2016) Impact of short-term interest rate on exchange rate: the case of Turkey. Procedia Econ Finance 38:195–202

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter J (1954) History of economic analysis. Oxford University Press, NY

    Google Scholar 

  • Senay Ozge, Sutherland Alan (2019) Optimal monetary policy, exchange rate misalignments and incomplete financial markets. Journal of International Economics 117:196–208

  • Seven U, Yetkiner H (2016) Financial intermediation and economic growth, does income matter? Econ Syst 40(1):39–58

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simo-Kengne BD, Miller SM, Gupta R, Aye GC (2015) Time-varying effects of housing and stock returns on US consumption. J Real Estate Finance Econ 50(3):339–354

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Singleton K (1987) Speculation and the volatility of foreign currency exchange rates. Carnegie-Rochester Conf Ser Public Policy 26:9–56. https://doi.org/10.1016/0167-2231(87)90020-0

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Snowdon B, Vane HR (2005) Modern macroeconomics: its origins, development and current state. Edward Elgar Publishing, Cheltenham

    Google Scholar 

  • Solarin A, Hammoudeh S, Shahbaz M (2018) Influence of economic factors on disaggregated Islamic banking deposits: evidence with structural breaks in Malaysia. J Int Finan Markets Inst Money 55:13–28

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tayebi SK, Sadeghi A (2017) The impacts of international sanctions and other factors affecting exchange rate in Iran. J Econ Res (tahghighat-E-Eghtesadi) 52(3):641–661

    Google Scholar 

  • Taylor P, Peel A (2000) Nonlinear adjustment, long-run equilibrium and exchange rate fundamentals. J Int Money Finance 19(1):33–53

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Terra FHB, Arestis P (2017) Monetary policy in the post Keynesian theoretical framework. Braz J Polit Econ 37:45–64

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thampanya N, Wu J, Nasir MA, Liu J (2020) Fundamental and behavioral determinants of stock return volatility in ASEAN-5 countries. J Int Finan Markets Inst Money 65:101193

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tobin J (1965) Money and economic growth. J Econ Soc. https://doi.org/10.2307/1910352

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Toraman C, Başarir Ç (2014) The long run relationship between stock market capitalization rate and interest rate: co-integration approach. Procedia Soc Behav Sci 143:1070–1073

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Valcarcel VJ (2012) The dynamic adjustments of stock prices to inflation disturbances. J Econ Bus 64(2):117–144

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Walsh CE (2010) Monetary Theory and Policy. The MIT Press Cambridge Massachusetts: Third Edition.

  • Wright RE (2012) Finance, banking, and money

  • Yartey CA (2008) The determinants of stock market development in emerging economies: is South Africa different? SSRN J. https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1094214

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yeyati EL, Sturzenegger F (2010) Monetary and exchange rate policies. In: Handbook of development economics, vol 5, Elsevier, pp 4215–4281

Download references

Acknowledgements

Not applicable.

Funding

This study has not been funded by any institution or government.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Contributions

AS, HM, AHS, KA, and PR contributed to the design and implementation of the research, the analysis of the results, and the writing of the manuscript. All the authors read and approved the final manuscript.

Author Information

AS is Ph.D. candidate in economics at Shiraz university. HM, AHS, and PR are orderly associate professor, professor, and Assistant professor at Shiraz university. KA is professor at the university of Isfahan.

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Abdorasoul Sadeghi.

Ethics declarations

Competing interests

The authors declare that they have no competing interests.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Supplementary Information

Additional file 1.

The results of ADF test.

Rights and permissions

Open Access This article is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License, which permits use, sharing, adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons licence, and indicate if changes were made. The images or other third party material in this article are included in the article's Creative Commons licence, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the material. If material is not included in the article's Creative Commons licence and your intended use is not permitted by statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from the copyright holder. To view a copy of this licence, visit http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Sadeghi, A., Marzban, H., Samadi, A.H. et al. Financial intermediaries and speculation in the foreign exchange market: the role of monetary policy in Iran’s economy. Economic Structures 11, 13 (2022). https://doi.org/10.1186/s40008-022-00271-x

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Revised:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1186/s40008-022-00271-x

Keywords

JEL Classification